Chapter 5 of C. Chase-Dunn and Thomas D. Hall, Rise and Demise:
Comparing World-Systems, Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
The Semiperiphery:
Seedbed of Change
In this
chapter we propose that core/periphery hierarchies are important structural
elements in the reproduction of world-systems and that semiperipheral locations
within core/periphery structures are important loci of forces that transform
world-systems. The comparative study of core/periphery hierarchies began with
several older works on "frontiers" (e.g., Lattimore 1940; McNeill
1964; Adams 1977), but the task of sorting out the different types of regional
dominance/dependence relations and examining the importance of these for the
dynamics of social development is yet in its infancy.
Here
we discuss our general conceptualization of the semiperiphery. Then we consider four different, but
related, general formulations of a theory of social change. Finally we examine
several types of social change that may be understood as instances of semiperipheral
development. We employ the conceptualizations of core/periphery
differentiation and core/periphery hierarchy already considered in Chapter 2.
The Semiperiphery Concept
The idea of the semiperiphery was first applied
to the modern world-system by Immanuel Wallerstein (1974a 1974b, 1979b) and it
has been developed and further explored by Giovanni Arrighi (1985). In various parts of Wallerstein's historical
and more theoretical analyses of the Europe-centered world-system he suggests
several meanings of the concept of the semiperiphery. In Chapter 2 we conceptualized the semiperiphery to include:
1. regions that mix both core and
peripheral forms of organization.
2. regions spatially located between core
and peripheral regions.
3. regions spatially located between two or
more competing core regions.
4. regions in which mediating activities
linking core and peripheral areas take place;
5. regions in which institutional features
are in intermediate in form between those forms found in adjacent core and
peripheral areas.
For
all of these we expect that semiperipheral regions will be dominated by the
core, but at the same time will dominate peripheral areas.[1] These five alternative forms of
semiperipherality are dependent on the nature of the core/periphery relations
that exist in any particular world-system.
This is because core, periphery, and semiperiphery are relational
concepts that are context-dependent. Nevertheless, we can abstract from
particular systems to consider whether or not there may be patterned
regularities that correspond to these analytical distinctions.
Four Approaches to Semiperipheral Development
Generally stated, we contend that semiperipheral
areas are likely to generate new institutional forms that transform system
structures and modes of accumulation. These changes often lead to the
upward mobility of these same semiperipheral actors in the core/periphery
hierarchy. We will see that the semiperiphery is fertile ground for social,
organizational, and technical innovation and has an advantageous location for
the establishment of new centers of power.
That is why the structural position of the semiperiphery has such
evolutionary significance.
Before
we turn to a consideration of several types of semiperipheral development that
illustrate this general principle we will summarize four earlier theoretical
approaches that utilized different language, but that overlap significantly
with the theory of semiperipheral development that we propose. The purpose of
this review is to provide several possible related approaches that may help us
to more clearly specify our general formulation and to fine-tune its
application to different types of circumstances. The four approaches we will consider are:
* Leon Trotsky's "laws of
uneven and combined development,"
* Alexander Gerschenkron's
"advantages of backwardness,"
*
Elman Service's "evolutionary potential,"and
* Carroll Quigley's
"institutionalization of an instrument of expansion."
Once we summarize the relevant parts of these
approaches we will show how they relate to our theory of semiperipheral
development.
Trotsky
Leon Trotsky (1932), a professional
revolutionary, wrote a history of the Russian revolution that began with a
discussion of the "historic laws" of "uneven and combined
development." He used this formulation to explain the "peculiar"
form of capitalist development in Russia and the stage-skipping evident (from a
Marxist view) in the sequence of Russian revolutionary transformations
compared to the English and French revolutions. We will see that both Service and Gerschenkron bear an
intellectual debt to Trotsky.
Trotsky's
most general formulations are as follows:
Unevenness, the most
general law of the historic process,
reveals itself most sharply and complexly in the destiny of the backward
countries. Under the whip of external
necessity their backward culture is compelled to make leaps. From the universal law of unevenness thus
derives another law which, for lack of a better name, we may call the law of combined
development--by which we mean a drawing together of the different stages of
the journey, a combining of separate steps, an amalgam of archaic with more
contemporary forms (emphasis in the original, Trotsky 1932:5 ff.).
And elsewhere Trotsky (1932:4) says:
A backward country
assimilates the material and intellectual conquests of the advanced
countries. But this does not mean that
it follows them slavishly... Although
compelled to follow after the advanced countries, a backward country does not
take things in the same order. The
privilege of historic backwardness--and such a privilege exists--permits, or
rather compels, the adoption of whatever is ready in advance of any specified
date, skipping a whole series of intermediate stages. Savages throw away their bows and arrows for rifles all at once,
without traveling the road which lay between those two weapons in the past. ...
The development of historically backward nations leads necessarily to a
peculiar combination of different stages in the historic process (Trotsky
1932:4-5).
Trotsky formulates the idea of the advantages
that "backward" societies have in being able to easily adopt or
innovate new forms, their ability to leapfrog "stages of
development," and the beneficial effects of being able to recombine
different elements.
Gerschenkron
Alexander Gerschenkron (1966), an economic
historian, further developed the idea of "the advantages of
backwardness" to explain the rapid
industrialization of certain countries that followed Britain's lead in the late
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries.
According to Gerschenkron countries that have certain natural and
organizational features favorable to industrialization can rapidly
industrialize by importing production technology, although the mechanisms they
employ and the sectoral path of economic change they follow will differ significantly
from those found in the original industrializer. Gerschenkron's discussion focussed primarily on Germany but he
also considered France and Russia.
Gerschenkron
noted that rapid secondary industrialization has aspects that are similar to
social movements in that economic change occurs across many sectors together
and the whole process involves a spirit that combines entrepreneurship with
collective enthusiasm. He emphasized
the importance of innovations in banking and state sponsorship of economic
development in these cases of "catching up" with the leader. According to Gerschenkron, the most
important "natural condition" that facilitates economic growth is
the availability of raw materials. Organizationally it is important to have a
unified state, as opposed to a collection of baronies (e.g., Germany before
1870). Serfdom is mentioned as a social organizational barrier to industrialization,
but Gerschenkron argued that the very lack of an industrial labor force might
facilitate rapid industrialization by encouraging the adoption of the most
up-to-date labor saving production technology.
Though
"backwardness" is generally argued to be a boon for rapid change,
under some circumstances Gerschenkron suggests that there is such a thing as
too much backwardness, as in his contrast between Russia and Germany. This is felicitous for our reinterpretation
of his approach in terms of a distinction between periphery and semiperiphery.
Service
The anthropologist Elman Service
first published his discussion of "evolutionary potential" in a
volume co-edited with Marshal Sahlins (Sahlins and Service 1960; Service 1971).
Service argues that development is usually discontinuous in space, with older
localities losing dominance to new centers.
He posits an interaction between adaptation
and adaptivity that produces this
uneven development in space. Adaptation
refers to an institutional adjustment to social and environmental pressures for
change. In contrast adaptivity is the ability to make
adaptive changes in response to social or environmental changes. A highly adapted society typically has very
low adaptivity (Service 1971). An
innovation in technology, social organization, or cultural institutions may
allow a society to become well-adapted to a natural and socio-economic
environment, but the very investment in that innovation, or constellation of
innovations, will, at a later point in time, inhibit the ability of the society
to adapt to new circumstances.
Adaptation usually involves specialization and the investment of
resources, while adaptivity is the quality of being able to make new changes.
Service
argues that a general process of social evolution -- the interaction between
adaptation and adaptivity -- accounts for the rise and fall of civilizations,
the spatial discontinuity of innovations in cultural techniques such as
writing, and the rise and fall of contemporary nation-states. He addresses the issue of the benefits and
costs of specialization raised in the literature on biological evolution, but
his formulation is clearly directed toward an explanation of uneven social
development. Older regions become
entrenched in earlier adaptations, while newly developing areas can "take
the best and leave the rest."
Service acknowledged his debt to Trotsky by quoting Trotsky on the
rapid, stage-skipping nature of Russian industrialization.
Quigley
Carroll Quigley (1979), a
historian, reformulated Arnold Toynbee's approach to the rise and fall of
civilizations. According to Quigley civilizations rise because semiperipheral
regions innovate instruments of expansion. These become institutionalized and
eventually the organizations stultify and decay, and then the process repeats
itself. Quigley (1979:366) actually used the term "semiperiphery."
His theory of rise and fall is formulated as a series of seven stages: mixture, gestation, expansion, age of
conflict, universal empire, decay, and invasion.
Quigley's
discussions of the stages of mixture and gestation are suggestive of
semiperipheral development. He says,
Every civilization, indeed every
society, begins with a mixture of two or more cultures. ... But such casual
cultural mixture is of little significance unless there comes in to existence
in the zone of mixture a new culture, arising from the mixture but different
from its constituent parts. .... The contributing societies may be
civilizations or merely producing societies (agricultural or pastoral) or
merely parasitic societies (with hunting or fishing).... Since cultural mixture occurs on the borders
of societies, civilizations rarely succeed one another in the same geographical
area, but undergo a displacement in space.... But on the borders of societies
there is a considerable mutual interpenetration of social customs, and there
arise, accordingly, alternative ways of satisfying human needs....
civilizations have generally arisen on the periphery of earlier civilizations.
Canaanite, Hittite, and Minoan civilizations arose on the edges of Mesopotamian
civilization (Quigley 1979:147-8).
Missing
from Gerschenkron and Trotsky is any consideration of the
mechanisms that bring about
organizational inertia and resistance to new adaptations in older core
regions. They discuss why
"backwardness" is an advantage, but not why being first is sometimes
a disadvantage. Service and Quigley do
consider both sides of these processes, but only in the most general
terms. Quigley wrote quite a lot about
ossification and efforts to reform institutions in old core regions.
One
problem with all these approaches is that they are formulated in terms of
levels or stages of development and therefore they largely ignore the
hierarchical and structural aspects of relations between societies within a
system. Backward or semiperipheral
areas catch up, but there is little attention to the importance of this as
upward mobility within a larger socially structured regional hierarchy.
All
these approaches however are compatible with the notion that a semiperipheral
location is a fruitful locus of transformational changes. But how might
world-system mechanisms of intersocietal domination and exploitation, and
processes of the development of underdevelopment fit in to this approach?
A
theory of semiperipheral development is not a claim that catching up or
becoming a new center of domination is possible for all regions. As we have
said, the extent to which core/periphery hierarchies and uneven development
are reproduced needs to be determined for each world-system. There have been world-systems in which the
spread effects of development are much stronger than the backwash effects of
underdevelopment. All hierarchical world-systems seem to experience uneven
development and cycles of political centralization/decentralization. We would
like to determine those aspects of semiperipheral development that are common
to different types of world-systems and those aspects that differ across types.
We
also need to point out that upward mobility and transformational action are not
necessarily the same thing. It is possible to succeed within a system without
transforming the rules of that system. And it is possible to change the logic
of social action without moving toward a more powerful or central location in a
system. But these two analytically separable features often do occur together.
We now turn to a consideration of cases in order to concretize this discussion.
Types of Semiperipheral Development
Once again we present a heuristic
typology. This, we promise, is the last. This time we want to designate
different kinds of semiperipheral development.
Some of these types overlap, and in one category there is only one
empirical case. Nevertheless in order to see construct the general notion it is
necessary to designate important differences between the following types:
1. conquest
by semiperipheral marcher chiefdoms
2. conquest by semiperipheral marcher
states
3. extensive and intensive commodification
by semiperipheral capitalist city-states
4. the rise of European hegemony -- an
upwardly mobile and transformational region,
5. the rise and fall of hegemonic core
states within the Europe-centered world-system, and
6. the
emergence of revolutionary challenges to capitalism in the semiperiphery of the
contemporary world-system.
Semiperipheral Chiefdoms
The phenomenon of the rise and fall
of chiefdoms has been studied in several different contexts by anthropologists.[2]
Chiefly polities interact with and compete with one another in sets that we
refer to as "interchiefdom systems."
The process of rise and fall involves competition among actual and potential
paramount chiefs. The territories and peoples under the control of a single
paramount grow as he succeeds in expanding his domain, usually by conquest. The
strains of maintaining an expanded domain often eventually lead to fragmentation
back into smaller independent polities. Marshall Sahlins (1972:141-8) describes
such a process for the case of precontact Hawai'i. Kristian Kristiansen (1991)
sees an analytically similar process in the cyclical changes that occurred
among polities in Bronze Age Scandinavia and Northern Europe. Along with the rise and fall phenomenon,
which is cyclical around some equilibrium of polity size, rises sometimes occur
that dramatically expand the scale of political organization by forming a
single polity that is much larger than any previous domain in the region.
Our
model of semiperipheral chiefdom conquest is taken from Patrick Kirch's
(1984:199-202) analysis of the evolution of Polynesian chiefdoms. Kirch presents a model of population growth
and lineage stratification for a single hypothetical Pacific island, though he
is thinking about the actual case of the big island of Hawai'i. The principle of successive primogeniture is
organized in Hawai'i (and in Polynesia generally) on the basis of conical clans.[3]
Genealogical lines are ranked in terms of closeness to the original ancestor,
and each person theoretically has a unique and intransitive position in this
system of ranked seniority. In practice this system operated as a theoretical
ideal. Competing claims were settled by force and genealogies were
reconstructed according to the outcomes of struggles among contending chiefs.
Nevertheless, the principle of genealogical seniority was an important one in
legitimating rule. In Hawai'i this principle evolved to include a radical
separation between chiefs and commoners, and the practice of brother-sister
marriages among sacred chiefs and chiefesses produced the highest possible
seniority for offspring.
Kirch's
model for colonization and population growth works as follows. A colonizing
party of Polynesians lands on an island and occupies the most favorable
location, usually on the windward side of the island. The windward side
receives the most rainfall and is generally the best for agriculture. Another
locational desideratum is offshore reefs that make for good fishing locations.
When the best location becomes fully occupied because of population growth this
community "hives off" --
splits in two -- to occupy the second most favorable location on the windward
side. The second community is headed by a chief who has less seniority than the
line that rules the original founding community. This process continues until
the windward side is occupied, at which point locations on the leeward side of
the island will be occupied in the order from best to least desirable. This
produces an island in which the ecological desirability of locations maps
perfectly with the kinship hierarchy.
Kirch
goes on to propose that after the island is filled continuing population growth
will generate pressures for either further migration to other islands or will
result in intensification of conflict and, eventually, pressures for
island-wide hierarchy formation. He suggests that successful conquest efforts
are likely to come from regions that are ecologically less favored such as the
leeward side of the island of Hawai'i, where large-scale irrigation was not
feasible (Kirch 1984:204). The junior line from a moderately marginal
ecological location had both the motive and the means to challenge the old
hierarchy.
This
model may be interpreted in world-system terms as follows. An intra-island
core/periphery structure emerged in which ecological factors and kinship
hierarchy corresponded. Continuing population growth created pressures for
intensification of production, intensification of conflict, and hierarchy
formation. These pressures eventually resulted in the formation of island-wide
chiefdoms by means of conquest, and the successful conqueror chief was likely
to come from one of the junior lines on the less ecologically-favored side of
the island. This is fascinating because
of its analytic similarity with a process known to occur in state-based systems
-- the formation of empires by semiperipheral marcher states.
Semiperipheral Marcher States
Secondary state-formation on the
marches[4]
has frequently been recognized as a phenomenon that is related to the rise and
fall of empires and the shift of hegemony within interstate systems. Of interest to a theory of semiperipheral
development are the processes that facilitate new and adaptive organizational
forms in marcher states and which inhibit or obstruct effective responses in
older core regions. Both of these have
been discussed in general terms by civilizationists, historians, and historical
sociologists. Rather than reviewing
this rather extensive literature we illustrate with a particular case, the
conquest of Sumer by Akkad.
There
have been many clear cases of semiperipheral marcher state conquest of older
core regions. A list of such cases known to most world historians would
include: the Akkadian empire, the
Kassites, Assur, Upper Egypt, the Medes, Achaemenids, Hittites, Hyksos,
Macedonia, Rome, Normans, Maurya, Shang, Chou, Manchus, Toltecs, Aztecs, Huari,
and Inka. In all these cases the named semiperipheral state conquered an older
core region and set up a new, larger core state. We mean to exclude conquerors that were either peripheral or who
simply decimated the old center without setting up a new regime. We also
exclude core-wide conquests by states that have long been in the core, or who
are restoring their former glory by making a comeback. The original position of
a conqueror within a core/periphery hierarchy is important, and the position of
the conquered region is important.
Conquests of regions that do not have core status do not count. Thus, this conceptualization contains two
components: the strength of the
emerging semiperipheral marcher and the strength of the old core. Some cores fall to marauders largely due to
their own internal processes of disorganization, while others are not rapidly
decaying but yet are not able to stave off powerful challengers. The intent of constructing the marcher-state
category is not to produce a pure ideal type, but rather to help specify a set
of processes of semiperipheral development that are very different from those
that operate in the other general categories we consider later.
Akkadian
Empire
The Sumerian interstate system and
world-economy lasted for seven hundred years before becoming transformed into
an empire for the first time by Sargon of Agade. These city-states interacted within the context of a regional
economic network that included a core/periphery division of labor with
surrounding pastoralists, rain-watered horticulturalists, and specialized
quarrying and manufacturing villages.
In the Sumerian core irrigated agriculture was the basis of the first
cities. These cities were politically
autonomous although they shared a pantheon and the first written language. The early states were theocracies governed
by temple priests and an assembly of lineage heads. As development of this form of organization spread up and down
the alluvial plain of the fertile crescent and as land appropriate to this form
of production became more scarce, the city states began to transform into
political organization based on an elected war leader, a Lugal. The power of the Lugal gradually increased
as warfare among city-states became more frequent and more important as a means
of controlling trade routes and access to raw materials. While recent evidence reveals the existence
of some forms of commodification of land and money economy, most production,
distribution, and trade was carried out by reciprocal kin networks linked
together by the political apparati of temple and palace.
Both
spread and backwash effects apparently operated in the core/periphery hierarchy
although the extent, nature and forms of domination and exploitation are
uncertain. The emphasis has been on
spread effects because it is obvious that irrigated agriculture diffused within
the Tigris-Euphrates flood plain and leap-frogged to other areas. It is also clear that surrounding pastoralists
and horticultural communities became specialized in production for exchange
with the core region. The core region
exported grain, but also textiles and other manufactured goods. We also know, however, that manufacturing
emerged also in remote villages near steatite (soapstone) deposits, as we have
seen due to transportation costs (see Chapter 2). Similarly, throughout the Bronze and Iron ages, metal-working was
often associated with mountain societies.
Friedman
and Rowlands (1977) contend that the main dynamic of exchange among cities
within the core area was based on a prestige goods economy. This, they argue,
made it hard for older core cities to monopolize power resources. Prestige goods economies are vulnerable to
copying or redefinition of the symbolic goods that signify high status. The pantheon of shared gods within the
Sumerian core indicates a struggle over the claims of different city deities to
superior position within the regional pantheon.
Igor
Diakonoff (1991) argued that exploitation within the Sumerian region was
primarily based on "internal" extraction of surplus product from
subjugated classes rather than "external" exploitation based on
political-military subjugation. He
contrasts this early period with a later period of "warrior empires"
in which conquest and exploitation became much more important. From the
surviving mythical literature of Sumer we know that kings took armies into
peripheral areas to obtain scarce objects such as wood for construction,
etc. However, Diakonoff claims that
such dominance relations were unstable.
The multicentric nature of the Sumerian core may have allowed peripheral
groups to play competing cities against one another. We know that the Sumerian cities attempted to control peripheral
resources by establishing settler colonies in peripheral regions (Algaze
1993). Yet, Michael Mann (1986) argues
that even these colonies were difficult to control under the circumstances of
high overland transport costs and severe logistic problems.
The
question of the importance of core/periphery hierarchy in the Sumerian or any
other world-system and the relative importance of spread vs. backwash effects
can only be determined by surveying the whole system. Kohl (1988) compares two peripheral regions, Transcauscasia and
Western Turkestan, and concludes that these two areas developed rather
autonomous and successful new centers in interaction with the Sumerian core in
the Bronze age. But a study that
focussed on the nineteenth century United States or twentieth century Japan (or
Korea or Taiwan) might conclude that upward mobility or rapid spread effects
are the usual case in the modern world-system.
Any decision about what is typical must be based on a survey of the
whole system and must take account of relative rates of development. Peripheries are not areas that do not
change at all. They are areas that develop core-like features more slowly than
the relevant core. Peripheralization
often involves the development in the periphery of social structural features
that impede further development toward the core. Any comparative study of core/periphery
hierarchies should take these matters into account.
Sargon,
the eventual king of the city of Agade, served as a young cup-bearer to the
king of Kish, one of the old cities of the Sumerian core in Southern
Mesopotamia. Sargon was originally
from Agade, perhaps a recently established city up river from the old core
region. Agade may have been populated by recently settled nomadic pastoralists
who had settled on the fringes of the Sumerian core (McNeill 1963). In any case
the residents of Agade were speakers of Akkadian, a Semitic (i.e. non-Sumerian)
language.[5]
The
Sumerian interstate system had already begun to exhibit the features of a
balance of power mechanism and the rise and fall of hegemons, but no city had
managed to conquer the whole core region.
Sargon led the Akkadians on a military campaign that defeated all the
other cities as well as much of the peripheral hinterland and erected the first
empire-state on Earth composed of formerly sovereign city-states.
There
is great disagreement about the relative importance of different factors that
led to the Akkadian conquest. Because of the scarcity of evidence it is
impossible to know for sure which interpretation is the best, but it is
nevertheless interesting to elaborate and distinguish between two models, both
of which are compatible with a general theory of semiperipheral
development. First, Mann's (1986)
developmental history of power techniques stresses the importance of military
technology and organization in the expansion of empires. In his chapter on the "first empires of
domination" Mann lays out an admirable model of the contradictory forces
of centralization and decentralization that operated in the ancient
empires. Mann (1986:130) also suggests,
"What had been hitherto semiperipheral areas became, in a sense, the new
core of civilization. Marcher lords
were the pioneers of hegemonic empire."
Speaking
explicitly of the Akkadian conquest, Mann claims that the recently settled
pastoralists combined peripheral with core-type military techniques in a way
that gave them an advantage over the older Sumerian core. The Sumerians used heavy infantry phalanxes
and cumbersome chariots drawn by equids, "perhaps onager and ass
hybrids" (Mann 1986:132). True
horses for riding or more mobile and speedy chariots had not yet been
developed. The core infantry were
"suited for slow, methodical campaigns whereby small densely
settled areas could be conquered
and defended. They arose from the
necessity to defend the early city-state and perhaps to conquer its immediate
neighbors" (Mann 1986:132 ff).
According
to Mann the Akkadians combined heavy infantry force with the use of a newly
developed composite bow. Mann's
contention that Sargon combined peripheral and core-type military techniques
rests on his claim that this type of bow was a peripheral product. He says, "But archery was apparently
developing rapidly from hunting practices, and the use of the bow seems to have
given a comparative advantage to the marchers if combined with infantry
force" (1986:133).
Mann
also asserts that the old core was in some ways "ripe for the
picking." The reliance on trade
routes became increasingly dependent on military protection as core development
created new needs and abilities in peripheral peoples. Though the old core still had a comparative
advantage in production, reliance on long distance trade exposed merchants to
raiding and tribute extraction.
Competition among core city-states often spurred the development of
semiperipheral marchers directly as core states made alliances with marchers in
order to win struggles within the core.
Mann's
(1986:141) discussion of "piecemeal treachery" suggests that
cleavages within the core state societies were developing. In the context of a discussion of the
difficult supply problems of an ancient conquering army, Mann points out that
campaigns approached one city-state at a time, and success was dependent on a
quick victory. Both superior force and
"coercive negotiations" were important. Mann says, "The defenders were not being offered much of a
choice. If they resisted, they might be
killed or enslaved; if they surrendered, their entire visible surplus might be
pillaged and their walls knocked down.
But a discontented cousin or younger son and his faction could be
promised more, and the city delivered up by them. This faction would be added to the army or left in charge of the
city" (1986:141).
A
second, rather different, yet complementary, picture is presented by the Soviet
Assyriologist Igor Diakonoff (1991).
Diakonoff focussed more on class relations in his explanation of how the
Akkadians conquered Sumer, although he also mentions the importance of Sargon's
use of the bow. Diakonoff (1991:85)
says, "It is entirely possible that Sargon had access to yew-tree (or
hazel-tree) groves in the foothills of Iran and Asia Minor, or that a composite
bow, glued together from horn, wood and sinews, had already been invented at
that time.[6]
Diakonoff
claims that the conquest by Akkad was based on both ethnic and class
factors. He says:
Legends of
much later times describe Sargon the Ancient as a man of very humble origin,
and there is no reason to doubt the credibility of this tradition. It was said that he was a gardener, the
adopted son of a water-bearer, and that he became a cupbearer of the lugal of
Kish.... The fact that Sargon had no roots in the traditional nomes and did not
depend on the nobility allowed him to draw his support from the common people,
forming a militia which might have been more or less voluntary (1991:84).
Another contributing factor to the
superior solidarity and motivation of the Akkadian army may have been based on
their status as Semitic speakers who had only recently settled down from
pastoralism (but see note 5 above).
Pastoralists generally have a kinship structure that promotes solidarity
among male lineage heads, and their experience with domesticated animals is
easily transformed into the husbanding of peoples (McNeill 1963; Hall
1991a). A kin-based reciprocal society
can more easily mobilize collective energies than a more stratified urbanized
society.
In contrast, in city-states private
property and the differentiation between temple and palace increased
competition within the urban ruling class, and increasing stratification
between classes made mobilization of the commoners for warfare more dependent
on material incentives and less susceptible to calls for sacrifice in the name
of the society. The "piecemeal
treachery" that Mann mentions may well have been a function of increasing
competition and conflict within the ruling classes of the old Sumerian
core. As to increasing interclass
polarization Diakonoff (1991:85) says:
In Lagash
the events which led to the coup of Uruinimgina attest to the accumulation of
many grievances against the prevailing order.
Sargon could encounter support everywhere. The poorest community members may have been interested in curbing
the inordinate growth of the nome aristocracy's power; service in Sargon's army
offered them hope for social and material betterment... But also within the
temple and the state economies, the personnel was stratified to such a degree
that it was always easy to find here people who were willing to help destroy
the nome order.
The disagreements over matters of fact
regarding the Akkadian conquest stem from problems of the availability of
evidence for this most ancient case of semiperipheral marcher conquest. This
makes it difficult to draw firm conclusions about which particular mechanisms
were important and about the general implications of this example for cases of
semiperipheral marcher conquest. The
Akkadian case is important because it was first, and because it transformed the
basic logic of a world-system more completely than did later instances. Ironically, as Diakonoff (1991:87) points
out, "Thus, the popular masses, who had supported Sargon, gained little
from his victory and eventually lost considerably, because a despotic and
bureaucratic form of government became more established in Mesopotamia and
lasted for millennia." The semiperipheral
region that combined elements of a peripheral kin-based mode of accumulation
with those of the core tributary mode succeeded in eliminating many of the
vestiges of the kin-based mode that had remained in the old core and in
establishing a more centralized, more exploitative, purer form of the tributary
mode than had ever existed before.
In a related, but somewhat different
approach to the phenomenon of semiperipheral marcher states Randall Collins
(1978) contends that the advantages of states in the marchlands is primarily
geomilitary. Because they are near the edge of the core "heartland"
they do not need to defend several borders at once and so they can concentrate
their resources on a strategy of conquest that adds territory sequentially
without threats from the rear. The disadvantage of older core powers is that
they must defend themselves from many sides and so their resources are spread
thinly. This explanation may account for some of the semiperipheral marcher
state phenomenon but we doubt that the purely geopolitical advantages of
location on the marches is the most important factor. The exact combination of
elements that allowed semiperipheral marchers to conquer older cores
undoubtedly varied from instance to instance, and these different combinations
also varied in their degree of fit with a general theory of semiperipheral
development. Only a comprehensive study
of a large and representative number of instances of semiperipheral conquest
and failed attempts can sort out the general from the specific aspects of this
phenomenon.
Autonomous Capitalist City-states
The
historical process of commercialization within the states and empires dominated
by the tributary modes of accumulation has not received sufficient scholarly
attention. It has been ignored because
of the vociferous debate between those who focus on the differences between the
ancient and the modern world and those others who argue that the instinct to
truck and barter is a universal feature of human nature, and thus all societies
can be analyzed in terms of the model of "economic man." We side with Polanyi and the substantivists
with respect to the distinction between normative, political, and market-based
forms of social integration. We do not
think that market rationality is "natural." Rather, as Marx claimed, the market and the commodification of aspects of life are
socially constructed institutions.
The debate between the substantivists
and the formalists has clouded the analysis of the historical development of
commodified forms within the context of normative and tributary modes of
production. The substantivists tend to
argue that either market forces did not exist in the ancient world, or that
they were so encumbered as to be unimportant.
The primitivists, such as Weber (1981) and Finley (1973) argue that
ancient capitalism was fundamentally different from modern capitalism and that
the dynamics of ancient society were not importantly affected by market
forces. This debate about similarities
and differences has obscured the study of the actual processes of
commodification of land, labor, wealth, and goods and the causes and
consequences of commodification for the dynamics of development within the
tributary modes of accumulation. The
fact that market relations are not dominant does not by itself prove that their
existence in certain spheres is unimportant, and in any case, since we know
that capitalist production eventually became the dominant mode of accumulation,
and since we want to know how modes become transformed, it makes sense to study
the actual processes of commercialization and their agents.
Our third type of semiperipheral
development focusses on capitalist city-states in the semiperipheral
interstices of empires dominated by the tributary mode of accumulation. What do we mean by capitalism in this
setting? We reject the dichotomous
distinction between ancient and modern capitalism in favor of the notion of degrees
of commodification. Even within
modern capitalism perfectly operating price-setting markets are a rarity,
especially for "problematic" commodities such as labor. The extent to which competitive bidding by
buyers and sellers sets exchange ratios (prices) is a variable that is
influenced by the operation of both normative and political (coercive)
regulation. Capitalism has become the
dominant mode of accumulation in a socio-economic system when market forces
have greater weight in the determination of the dynamics of growth,
reproduction, and decline (and greater weight in the competitive struggle
determining the distribution of social resources) than normative or
political-coercive forms of regulation.
In the ancient world money (commodified wealth), markets, interest,
commodified labor, and the production of commodities were more limited and less
purely developed than these institutions have become in the modern world.
Commodification was a process that was uneven. But there were increasingly
significant degrees of commodification, and some actors are helpfully
understood as having been merchant capitalists and production capitalists in
the ancient world-systems.
The question of the control of states
by "capitalists" is also
problematic. Control is also a
variable, and is always shared or conditioned to some extent. Control is most easily seen in its
effects. State policy is bent toward
the provision of protection rent in
Frederick Lane's (1973, 1979) sense.[7] Lane defines protection rent as the
differential returns received by merchants whose trading efforts are supported
by a cost-efficient and protection-providing state. This assumes that the point of state policy is to maintain (and
extend) the conditions for profitable trade at minimal cost. This definition can be extended easily to
cover the foreign and domestic policies that are beneficial to capitalist
accumulation through production, as well as trade. No state measures up to the pure type because all states must
make compromises to some extent with other groups besides capitalists, but
some of the autonomous capitalist-dominated city states of antiquity approach
the pure case closely.
The mix between those emphasizing merchant capitalism (accumulation
through exploiting price-differentials across different regions) and production
of commodities for sale varies across cities and, over time, within
cities. Some cities combine these forms
of capitalism with a more typical (in the context of tributary mode empires)
accumulation through taxation and tribute.
There are also important differences
depending upon the sectors in which capitalist production is conducted. The Greeks combined production of wheat,
olives, and wine for use and for sale, a partially-commercialized economy that
required control over agricultural land (Rostovtzeff 1941). This was a more
commodified mode of accumulation than that found within the large territorial
empires, but it was less commodified than the approach employed by the
Phoenicians. The Phoenician city-states concentrated on merchant capitalism and
the production of manufactures for export.
This meant that they did not need to control large tracts of land. Thus, their cities were built on
promontories that could be protected from armies by naval force. They did utilize nearby land for truck
gardens to supplement staple food imports, but this did not weigh them down
with the necessity to control large land areas. This advantage for capitalism is emphasized by Fernand Braudel
(1984) in his study of merchant cities in Europe.
Another complication in the
delineation of a class of autonomous capitalist city-states is their degree of
autonomy. One reason why the autonomous
city-states of antiquity were semiperipheral is that they were on the edges of,
or the boundaries between, large territorial empires. These empires were the
dominant core polities of the ancient world-systems. Spatially the capitalist city-states were often located such that
they could easily mediate trade between the core empires and peripheral regions. But the autonomy of these cities
varied. Often they acted as allies to
one or another empire, and they were sometimes swallowed up by imperial
expansion (Frankenstein 1979).
Some cities within empires were
allowed partial autonomy for merchant and production capitalism, and this was
increasingly the case as tributary mode conquerors became more sophisticated
about how to extract surplus. As
empires themselves became more commercialized, kings and emperors learned to
tax merchants rather than expropriating them outright, and conquered cities
were granted some autonomy to pursue production and trade. The point here is that autonomy is another
variable. We focus primarily on those
cities that had formal sovereignty, but we recognize that merchant cities
within tributary empires sometimes played an important role in the expansion of
commodification (e.g., Tlateloco, Canton, Babylon, Osaka).
Some cases of sovereign semiperipheral
capitalist city states are: Dilmun,
Byblos, Tyre, Sidon, Carthage, Malacca, Venice, Florence, Genoa, Antwerp, and
the cities of the Hanseatic League. Another list might be constructed of
semi-autonomous towns that carried on extensive trade as a result of being
located on overland routes, such as those on the Silk Road that made a living
by linking the distant cores of Eurasia. Some of these, like the specialized
maritime cities, obtained much of their basic foodstuffs through trade, and
served as agents of commodification.
Karl Polanyi's students and colleagues
(Polanyi, et al. 1957) utilized the concept of the "port of trade" to
characterize long distance state-administered exchange in the context of the
early empires. The idea is that real
price-setting markets are not operating because exchange is regulated by
political deals among states, and merchants operate primarily as state
agents. Subsequent research has
revealed new evidence that some of the cases studied by Polanyi and his
students did indeed have independent merchants trading on their own account and
extensive monetization (e.g., Curtin 1984).
Polanyi's overall implication is that ports of trade are simply
reflections of the dominant tributary mode of production. They supposedly do
not constitute important agents of social change toward a more commercialized
type of economy. It may be the case
that some cities in neutral zones mediating trade between empires truly were
inert ports of trade in the Polanyian sense. But Polanyi did not choose to
analyze most of the maritime city-states we have listed above. These were agents of market forces within
the interstices of tributary empires and their activities were an important
stimulus to the further commodification of large regions, including peripheral
areas and the tributary empires themselves.
Marx's (1967:Chap. 20) analysis of
merchant capitalism discusses how, under some circumstances, the action of
merchants in buying cheap and selling dear not only equalizes prices across
different regions but also encourages production for exchange and
specialization. For Marx labor only
becomes a commodity under the wage system in which workers sell their labor
power (time) to capitalists. Market forces subject producers to the constraint
of average "socially necessary
labor time."[8] This means that market forces will eliminate
forms of production that are inefficient in terms of the utilization of labor,
i.e. new forms of labor-saving technology will be implemented and drive older
forms out. Marx considered wage labor to be the only form of labor mobilization
appropriate to capitalism. While we
agree that this is the most flexible form (allowing market forces to most
easily restructure the production process), we note that various other forms of
partly commodified labor (e.g., chattel slavery) and even uncommodified labor
(e.g., serfdom) have been used for commodity production in both the ancient
modern world-systems. Though this kind
of capitalism was not as extensively commodified as the modern kind is, it
should be studied rather than swept under the rug.
The processes by which regions became
integrated into a larger market economy began with the commodification of goods
through the carrying trade of merchants. Merchants move things from places
where prices are low to areas where prices are high. The ability to do this depends on the existence of forms of transportation
that are economic in the sense that the transport costs do not consume the
profit. A human carrier cannot
economically carry corn further than the distance over which he will eat his
pack full of corn (Drennan 1984). And this is true regardless of the mode of
accumulation. Thus transport costs are
the main determinants of the concentric rings within which bulk goods and
lighter prestige goods move, and this is also an important reason why
trade-based cities are usually built near waterways.
Another reason why semiperipheral
capitalist city-states tend to rely on water transportation and naval power has
to do with their interaction with conquest-based tributary empires. Merchant
cities located inland are much more susceptible to conquest than those located
on coasts, promontories or islands that can be supplied and defended by naval
forces. These maritime powers usually
combine merchant-shipping with naval supremacy, and are often considered
"pirates" by their competitors.
But it is mistaken to characterize
many of the cities on our list simply in terms of merchant capitalism. In many cases they specialized in manufacturing
particular products for export in conjunction with their carrying trade, and
this aspect of their operation also functioned to expand and deepen market
demand. The Phoenician cities of Sidon
and Tyre borrowed glass-making technology from the Egyptians and manufactured
relatively cheap glass vases which they exported to the entire Mediterranean
littoral. The Carthaginians reproduced
Greek-style pottery and statuary for export.
Besides reminding us of Taiwan, these examples show how the Phoenicians
were agents of technological change through the operation of socially necessary
labor time within an ancient world-system.
Semiperipheral capitalist city-states
performed the role of trade diasporas (see Chapter 1; Curtin 1984). They not only encouraged commodity
production and exchanges by providing demand for local surpluses, but they also
helped to forge the intercultural bases of regularized cross-cultural trade by
familiarizing people with the products and ideas of distant lands. This was
transformational action, but not upward mobility as long as the tributary modes
of accumulation remained dominant. It was only with the emergence of a dense
and very commercialized regional system in Europe that capitalist states moved
from the semiperiphery to the core.
"The Rise of the West"
Although
we deal at greater length with the "rise of the West" later (in Part
III), we also need to consider it briefly here as a type of semiperipheral
development. The rise of the West
combined two different types of semiperipheral development -- marcher states
and capitalist city states -- to produce a new form that might be labeled a
"semiperipheral marcher world-system." But because Europe was never really a separate system, it should
rather be called a semiperipheral marcher region.
The confusion about Europe's
peripherality can be resolved by analysis at four spatial scales: developments within Europe; changes that
occurred in Europe's peripheral and then semiperipheral relationship with the
Eastern Mediterranean and West Asian core region; Europe's links (sometimes
interrupted) with the other core regions in India and China; and changes that
were occurring in the Afroeurasian PGN as a whole. The three separate cores of the Afroeurasian system constituted
separate political/military networks (PMNs) that had long been linked in a
larger prestige goods and information network (see Chapter 8).
At first Europe was a periphery, then
a semiperiphery of the Near Eastern core.
Then it began to form its own internal core region, and to dominate its
own periphery. Finally it came to
dominate the older cores of the Near East, India and China. These shifts are
considered in detail in Chapters 8,10 and 11.
The Rise and Fall of Hegemonic Core States
According
to Wallerstein, hegemony is a
situation in which one core state has an unusually large share of world
economic and military power over other core states. Under this definition, there have been three hegemonies in the
Europe-centered system since the seventeenth century CE: the Dutch, the British, and the United States. In the modern world-system, we argue, the
context is a larger world-economy in which capitalism has become the dominant
mode of accumulation. Thus the nature of competition and the types of
institutional innovations employed by successful rising semiperipheral powers
are somewhat different.
All of the three states that became
hegemonic core states were semiperipheral before they achieved core status. The
Netherlands was a wetland where Protestant rebels from Antwerp retreated from
the Spanish Duke of Alva. The strongest
European state at the time was Spain. Protestantism was a religion of the
semiperiphery, an ideology that democratized access to the deity and challenged
the authority of the old core. The Dutch Republic uniquely combined features of
earlier capitalist city-states with a federalist nation-state policy dominated
by the merchants and production-capitalists of Amsterdam (Taylor 1994). The
Dutch had the first capitalist state with core status.
England was a relatively strong
medieval state, but its role in the international economy was as an exporter of
raw materials, mainly wool, to manufacturing cities on the continent. Efforts
to gain control of trade (e.g., the expulsion of Jews, formation of the
Merchant Adventurers) and to support import substitution began in the time of
Queen Elizabeth, as did colonialism and the raiding of Spanish galleons by
state-sanctioned privateers. The
eventual success of these policies in expanding trade and manufacturing for
the home and export market led England to core status in the eighteenth
century, and then to hegemony in the nineteenth.
The United States was peripheral
during the eighteenth century, although the "triangle trades"
shipping, ship-building, and some manufacturing had already developed in New
England before the Revolutionary War.
The South remained a classical producer of peripheral raw materials
employing coerced (slave) labor until the Civil War, but the North and the West
developed core capitalism. Aspiring
core capitalists and statesmen struggled politically against those who had a
vested interest in the export of raw materials to the European core from 1816
until the Civil War. The north and the south struggled over control of the
federal state and such issues as tariffs and land-distribution policy. The western farmers shifted their
sympathies in synchrony with the world market price of wheat. When the price was high they supported free
trade. When the price was low they supported the Henry Clay's "American
System" -- tariff protection for industry and government-subsidized
transportation links (Chase-Dunn 1980).
The U.S. was semiperipheral in the sense that it contained within it a
mixture of core and peripheral activities, and U.S. merchants mediated trade
between the European core and the Caribbean and Latin American periphery. The U.S. reached core status in the 1880s,
and economic hegemony after World War I. Only after World War II was
political/military hegemony embraced.
The hegemonic sequence, stages of hegemony, and the causes of both rise
and decline have been analyzed using comparisons of the three hegemons with
each other and with other core and peripheral states within the modern
world-system (Chase-Dunn 1989:Ch. 9).
Though these cases fit the general model of semiperipheral development,
a detailed comparison of the mechanisms of rise and fall with those operating
in earlier semiperipheral marcher states reveals important differences as well
as general similarities. In the
capitalist mode of accumulation, the paths to success of these rising hegemons
relied much more on comparative advantage in the production of commodities and
the use of military power to protect trade routes and access to raw material
inputs to commodity production. Military power was used to facilitate
capitalist accumulation. In earlier semiperipheral marcher states coercive
power was itself the direct mechanism of accumulation. This is simply another
way of saying that the logic of competition shifted away from the extraction
of taxes and tribute by military force to the accumulation of profit through
commodity production.
The most successful states in the
modern capitalist world-system have been capitalist states. Of course, there
have been other "paths of development" within the modern
world-system. Prussia and Japan attained
early success through state-building and military strength that was much more
reminiscent of the tributary strategy, only later converting to commodity
production. The case of Russia/USSR was
also very different. The dependence of
capitalism on the interstate system (see Chase-Dunn 1989:Ch. 7) has reproduced
the logic of geopolitics even while commodity production became the dominant
mode of accumulation.
Another important difference between
uneven development within the modern world-system and in earlier systems is in
the degree of disruption caused by the fall of old core centers and the rise of
new ones. Since the capitalist
world-economy is politically organized as a permanently multicentric interstate
system, with multiple competing states in the core, the process of rise and
fall of hegemons appears to be more routinized and less disruptive for the
system as a whole. When tribute and
taxation are the main forms of accumulation, the failure of an empire is quite
disruptive of all social relations. But in a system of generalized commodity
production the center of power, based now more on competitive advantage in
production, can move from Holland to England to the United States with
relatively less disruptive consequences for the operation of the system as a
whole. For example, the fall of the
western portion of the Roman Empire was not fatal for the European region, but
recovery took a long time, at least compared to the consequences of the decline
of a modern hegemon. We contend that
this difference is largely a consequence of the transformation of the mode of
accumulation.
The most problematic instances of
semiperipheral-based change are actual or potential challenges to
capitalism. Trotsky's approach can be
extended to consideration of the socialist experiment in the Soviet Union. Chase-Dunn has argued elsewhere (1982,
1992c) that the Soviet Union never successfully established an autonomous and
self-reproducing socialist mode of production.
Nevertheless, it posed the most powerful challenge to capitalism in the
modern world-system. China may pose a
similar challenge. If so, both would be
cases of challenge from semiperipheral regions. To the degree that this is so, they support our argument that
fundamentally new organizational forms, activities with very different logics
of operation, are likely to emerge first in semiperipheral areas where both
core and peripheral forms are combined and development is subjected to very
contradictory forces. We explore this
theme further in the following section and in Part IV.
Conclusions
We now
return to the discussion of theoretical problems in the light of our
consideration of the different types of semiperipheral development. The different vocabularies used by Trotsky,
Gerschenkron, Quigley, and Service are only semantic problems. Whether we talk of stages, phases, or levels
of development, or evolution is not really crucial. A more serious problem confronting the effort to formulate a
coherent theory of semiperipheral development is the potential for confusion
and circularity in the definitions of structural positions within a
core/periphery hierarchy. It could be true by definition that new cores are
previous semiperipheries, but this tautology would not explain anything.
When
we are considering the question of upward mobility--the moving of a
semiperipheral polity into core status (or hegemony or empire-formation)--we
need to distinguish between position in the core/periphery hierarchy and
changes in that position. In the modern
world-system this is accomplished by examining relative indicators of
world-system position comparatively at one point in time and rates of change
over time in those indicators relative to the population of competing
actors. For example, if we can
consider, as some do (e.g., Arrighi and Drangel 1986), GNP per capita to be a
good indicator of a country's position in the contemporary core/periphery
hierarchy, then the growth rate of GNP per capita can be used as an indicator
of change or stability in world-system position when it is compared to the
growth rates of all the other countries in the system. A semiperipheral country will have a GNP per
capita that is roughly intermediate in the distribution of crossnational
comparisons, while an upwardly mobile semiperipheral country will have a
relatively high economic growth rate (e.g., South Korea, Taiwan).
Of course an entire army of
researchers and bureaucrats have worked on methods of national economic
accounting and crossnational comparisons for fifty years to produce the
concepts, operations, and actual data that make these quantitative measurements
possible, and even so, the data are skimpy before 1950. But the existence of such a system for the
global political economy demonstrates that the distinction between position in
a core/periphery hierarchy and change in that position can, in principle, be
meaningful for earlier intersocietal hierarchies. The solution is to develop concrete understandings of the forms
that earlier core/periphery hierarchies have taken, and to conceive of mobility
within these hierarchies as relative to the development of the existing
intersocietal network as a whole.
Our discussion of semiperipheral
marcher states intentionally excluded both core and peripheral conquerors, but
a real test of our hypothesis must include these, as well as conquerors who
emerged from regions previously unconnected with the relevant world-system. Our proposition is that conquerors from the
semiperiphery are most likely to perform empire-formation and the expansion of
empires, while peripheral or external invaders are more likely to be destroyers
or to form very short-lived states. Transformational action by semiperipheral
marcher states involves the expansion and further institutionalization of the
tributary mode of production.
The relationship between nomadic
pastoralists and states supports these contentions (for more details see
Chapter 8 and Hall 1989, 1991a). Most
often nomadic pastoralists are employed as border guards of empires (e.g.,
Comanches, Cossacks). Those that succeed in conquering core areas are rarely
successful in forming long-lasting empires.
It is rather recently-settled pastoralists who have already undergone
some state-formation of their own who are the prime candidates to be
empire-builders. In the act of settling
down on the edges of a core region these nomadic societies become
semiperipheral (e.g., Akkad). A
comprehensive test of this thesis would need to survey the universe of
empire-formations and classify the core/periphery positions of all the empire
builders.
David Wilkinson's (1991:124-145)
examination of cores and core shifts in
thirteen political-military networks (PMNs) is one way to solve the
circularity problem mentioned above.
There are several logical alternatives involved in core shifts. The
newly risen core power may be a formerly semiperipheral city or state, but it
may also be: a resurgent older core
state, a peripheral people that conquer and destroy a core region but do not
establish a new core state, or a peripheral people that conquer an old core and
do establish a new core state. These logical alternatives eliminate the
tautology. Wilkinson's study provides support our hypothesis, but differences
in our respective definitions of semiperiphery cloud that support.[9]
Wilkinson's survey of "core
shifts" in thirteen PMNs reveals that the most frequent type of core shift
is one in which a semiperipheral state conquers an old core and creates a new
hegemonic power. But other types of core shifts also occur frequently.
Wilkinson notes a pattern that he calls a "shuttle" in which hegemony
moves back and forth between two regions. And there are many cases of
semiperipheral ascent, the rise to core status of semiperipheral regions that
do not conquer the old core.
The
theory of semiperipheral development also claims that semiperipheral areas are
disproportionately the locus of agents of major social transformations. In order to evaluate this broad claim we
would need to define and operationalize the differences between activities that
simply reproduce the dominant mode of accumulation from activities that expand
and develop the dominant mode or that expand the logic of a new mode.
Do both success within the modern
world-system and transformative influences on the mode of accumulation come
disproportionately from semiperipheral countries? Obviously we are not arguing that all semiperipheral areas are
transformative or upwardly mobile.
Rather, our contention is that those countries that display the greatest
successes at capitalism have been formerly semiperipheral, and also that the
most significant challenges to the logic of capitalism have emerged from the
semiperiphery. We submit that the first
claim, that the most successful capitalist countries (i.e. the hegemons) were
indeed previously semiperipheral. This does not establish that
semiperipherality as a prerequisite to success. What we have not addressed is why some challengers succeed and others
do not. This is a much more complicated
matter.
The transformation to a socialist mode
of accumulation is even more problematic.
We contend that the large Communist states -- China and the Soviet
Union-- underwent the most transformative structural changes toward socialism,
though they did not succeed in establishing a self-reproducing socialist mode
of accumulation. Russia/USSR was
obviously semiperipheral. But what about China? By most economic measures (e.g., GNP per capita) China is still a
peripheral country. But we contend that
China was never completely peripheralized as a result of incorporation in to the
expanding Europe-centered world-system, though regions within China were. The cultural and political strength of China
enabled it to resist colonization by the West and to maintain political unity
and some military strength. These features contributed to the strong
establishment of institutional features of socialism that have proven difficult
to reverse despite more than a decade of effort. These features also contribute to China's upward mobility within
the capitalist world-economy. Aspects
of socialism have also emerged within both core and peripheral countries but we
submit that these have been less transformative than the changes that occurred
in China and the Soviet Union.
We are not arguing that socialism is
impossible in the core or the periphery, but rather that it is more likely to
emerge strongly in the semiperiphery.
This is because the modern core/periphery hierarchy stimulates class
struggle in the semiperiphery, while it cross-cuts and dampens it in both the
core and the periphery (Chase-Dunn 1989:Ch. 10). The current (1990s) phase of "free market reforms" in
both the former Soviet Union and China do not vitiate our argument. It may well be that of these regions may
invent a new mode of accumulation that is neither socialism nor capitalism.
While that remains to be seen, it is clear that semiperipheral regions will
continue to challenge the capitalist world-system in various ways.
The notion of semiperipheral development is only part of our theoretical explanation of the historical evolution of world-systems. In the next chapter we consider a sequence of interactions among processes of population growth, environmental degradation, population pressure, conflict, hierarchy formation, and the intensification of production. Iterations of these interactions, along with the transformations of modes of accumulation, account for the main patterns of social change over the last ten thousand years in which myriad small-scale egalitarian world-systems have become incorporated in to a single global capitalist system.
Notes
[1]. This last form of semiperipherality has been
termed "subimperialism" by Marini (1972).
[2]. See Anderson (1994) for a recent useful
review.
[3]. A conical clan is an extensive common
descent group, ranked and segmented along geneological lines and patrilineal in
ideological bias.
[4]. March lands or the marches are terms for
border or frontier areas. A
"marcher" is one who inhabits such areas. Hence a marcher state is a border or frontier state.
[5]. Some scholars of the ancient Near East
dispute the idea that the Akkadians were recently-settled pastoralists. It is
contended that Sumerian and Akkadian speakers had resided next to one another
in this region for millennia. Evidence relevant for determining the
core/periphery position of Agade in the Sumerian system is thin. The
archaeological site of Agade has never been found. But documentary evidence
supports the claim that it was located well north, up-river, of the old
Mesopotamian core region, and the fact that the Akkadian empire substituted the
Akkadian language for the older written Sumerian supports the interpretation of
the Akkadian conquerors as semiperipheral marchers.
[6]. Contrary to Mann's claim that Sargon used
heavy infantry, Diakonoff (1991:85) says, "Sargon and his successors
changed the traditional battle tactics by replacing the small, heavily armed
detachments with large masses of lightly-armed, mobile warriors, who either
fought in chain formations or dispersed."
[7]. Mann (1986) uses the term "protection
rent" to mean extraction of surplus by coercive taxation of
merchants. We would classify this as
one form of the tributary mode. Lane's
usage suggests rather the nature of policy and action taken by capitalist
states.
[8]. "Socially necessary labor time" is
the amount of labor required to produce a commodity using the current standard
technology.
[9]. Wilkinson's distinction between
semiperiphery and periphery is different from our definition. For Wilkinson (1991:121) a semiperiphery is
"strongly connected to the core (younger, fringeward, remote, more
recently attached, weaker, poorer, more backward)," while a periphery is
"weakly connected...(nomads; peasant subsistence producers not yet
attached to a city;...)." In our
concept full-blown peripheries are strongly connected, but they are even
poorer, weaker, etc. than semiperipheries. Thus Wilkinson's semiperiphery
contains both our semiperiphery and at least part of our periphery. This difference means that we cannot
completely rely on Wilkinson's survey.
It is beyond our means now to recode Wilkinson's survey so we can only
counsel caution regarding inferences made here based on his catalogue of core
shifts.
This said, we can still learn from
examining Wilkinson's survey. All of
his cases (PMNs) are state-based systems with cities larger than 10,000 in
population. So chiefdom world-systems are excluded. Many core shifts do not
involve conquest of an old core state, but rather the rise in an adjacent
region of a new core area. We call these instances of "semiperipheral
ascent." There are also instances of "core return" in which a
formerly powerful core state resumes hegemonic status.