Power and Size:

Urbanization and Empire Formation in World-Systems

 

Christopher Chase-Dunn

chriscd@mail.ucr.edu

Alexis Alvarez

alexisalvarez@earthlink.net

Institute for Research on World-Systems

University of California, Riverside

DRAFT 01-05-02

(5360 words)

 

Abstract: This paper contains an overview of earlier research on city and empire growth/decline phases and new evidence on the relationship between urban growth, city-size distributions and the rise and fall of empires in separate world-systems that merged into a single global system over the past four millennia.

 

The Neo-Assyrian Empire at its largest in 650 BCE.

 

To be presented at the Comparative Social Analysis Workshop, Center For Comparative Social Analysis, Department of Sociology, UCLA, January 24, 2002. An earlier version was presented at the session on “Systems of cities: past and present” at the annual meeting of the American Sociological Association, Anaheim, August 21, 2001.

The paper is available at http://irows.ucr.edu/research/citemp/powersize.htm


 

 

            Earlier research has demonstrated the utility of studying settlement systems and networks of interacting polities as windows on the historical development of social complexity and hierarchy. By knowing the population sizes of settlements and the approximate territorial sizes of states and empires we can compare rather different time periods and regions in order to discover both regularities and uniquenesses.

            This paper briefly summarizes the results of earlier studies using city and empire sizes and presents new results on the relationships between changes in urban populations, city-size distributions and the territorial sizes of states and empires. Archaeologists often assume that the concentration of political power can be inferred from the rise of a size hierarchy of settlements – increases in the steepness of the settlement size distribution (e.g. Kowalewski 1982). This hypothesis can be tested by using existing data, though more certain results await the improvement and greater temporal resolution of data on city and empire sizes.

            Chase-Dunn and Willard (1993) examined urban growth and city-size distributions in nine different regional political/military networks (PMNs) [1] using data on city sizes from Tertius Chandler’s (1987) compendium. Political/military networks (PMNs) are interstate systems – systems of adjacent conflicting and allying states. David Wilkinson (1987) bounds these expanding and contracting systems of states as they merge or become incorporated into what Wilkinson calls the “Central System.” Chase-Dunn and Willard (1993) plotted changes in the Standardized Primacy Indices (a measure of the steepness of the city-size distribution) over time, and read descriptions of what was happening in the different systems to examine the hypothesis that changes in the city-size distribution was related to changes in the degree of political integration and the centralization of state power in nine different PMNs. They also accidentally discovered a synchronicity of changes in city size distributions and phases of urban growth/decline in the East Asian and the West Asian-Mediterranean PMNs over a long period from about 500 BCE to about 1500 CE.[2]

This latter discovery led to further research using data on the territorial sizes of empires gathered by Rein Taagepera (1978a, 1978b, 1979,1997). That analysis (Chase-Dunn, Manning and Hall 2000) found additional evidence for synchronicity between the East Asian and the West Asian-Mediterranean PMNs over this same two thousand year period, and confirmed what had also been indicated by scant city size data from India, that the Indic PMN was marching to a different drummer.

            These synchronicity results were further confirmed by additional analysis of the city data by Chase-Dunn and Manning (1998). That study examined synchronicities by comparing constant regions rather than PMNs. PMN boundaries change over time because of the expansion of the Central System, whereas specified regions that are held constant over time can constitute a different, but related, unit of analysis. Chase-Dunn and Manning found support for the synchronicity phenomenon using constant regions, and so this phenomenon is not likely to be an artifact of the way in which units of analysis have been constructed.

 

 

 

 

Power, Urban Growth and Urban Size Hierarchies

 

            This paper returns to the question asked in the Chase-Dunn and Willard (1993) study about the relationship between urban growth, city-size distributions and the rise and fall of empires. What is the relationship between the size of settlements and power in intergroup relations? Under what circumstances does a society with greater population density have power over adjacent societies with lower population density, and when might this relationship not hold?  Population density is often assumed to be a sensible proxy for relative societal power. Indeed Chase-Dunn and Hall employ high relative population density as a major indicator of core status within an intersocietal system (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997). But Chase-Dunn and Hall are careful to distinguish between “core/periphery differentiation” and “core/periphery hierarchy.” Only the latter constitutes actively employed intersocietal domination or exploitation, and Chase-Dunn and Hall warn against inferring power directly from differences in population density.

            In many world-systems military superiority is the key dimension of intersocietal relations. Military superiority is generally a function of population density and the proximity of a large and coordinated group of warriors to contested regions. The winner of a confrontation is that group that can bring the larger number of warriors together quickly.  This general demographic basis of military power is modified to some extent by military technology, including transportation technologies. Factors such as better weapons, better training in the arts of war, faster horses, better boats, greater solidarity among soldiers and their leaders, as well as advantageous terrain, can alter the simple correlation between size and power.

            The most important general exception (in comparative evolutionary perspective) to the size/power relationship is the phenomenon of semiperipheral development (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997:Chapter 4).  The pattern of uneven development by which formerly more complex societies lose their place to “less developed” societies takes several forms depending on the institutional terrain on which intersocietal competition is occurring.  Less relatively dense semiperipheral marcher chiefdoms conquer older core chiefdoms to create larger chiefly polities. Likewise, semiperipheral marcher states, usually recently settled peripheral peoples on the edge of an old region of core states, frequently are the agents of a new core-wide empire based on conquest. Less dense semiperipheral Europe was the locus of a virile form of capitalism that condensed in a region that was home to a large number of unusually proximate semiperipheral capitalist city-states. This development, and the military technology that emerged in the competitive and capitalist European interstate system, made it possible for less dense Europe to erect a global hegemony over the more densely populated older core regions of Eurasia. The more recent hegemonic ascent of formerly semiperipheral national states such as England and the United States are further examples of the phenomenon of semiperipheral development. 

            The phenomenon of semiperipheral development does not totally cut away the general observation of a correlation between power and size. What it shows is that this correlation can be overcome by other factors, and that these processes are not entirely random. Denser core societies are regularly overcome or out competed by less dense semiperipheral societies, but it does not follow that all semiperipheral or peripheral regions have such an advantage. On the contrary, the majority of low density societies are subjected to the power of more dense societies.  Semiperipheral development is a rather important exception to this general rule.

 

Why should a city system have a steeper city size distribution when there is a greater concentration of power? The simple answer is that large settlements, and especially large cities, require greater concentrations of resources to support their large populations. This is why population size has itself been suggested as an indicator of power (Taagepera, 1978a: 111). But these resources may be obtainable locally and the settlement size hierarchy may simply correspond to the distribution of ecologically determined resources. People cluster near oases in a desert environment. In such a case it is not the political or economic power of the central settlement over surrounding areas that produces a centralized settlement system but rather the geographical distribution of necessary or desirable resources. In many systems, however, we have reason to believe that relations of power, domination and exploitation do affect the distribution of human populations in space. Many large cities are as large as they are because they are able to draw upon far-flung regions for food and raw materials. If a city is able to use political/military power or economic power to acquire resources from surrounding cities it will be able to support a larger population than the dominated cities can, and this will produce a hierarchical city size distribution.

 

Of course the effect can also go the other way. Some cities can dominate others because they have larger populations, as discussed above. Great population size makes possible the assembly of large armies or navies, and this may be an important factor creating or reinforcing steep city size distributions.

 

The relationship between power and settlement systems is contingent on technology as well as political and economic institutions. Thus we expect to find that the relationship between urban growth and decline sequences and the growth decline sequences of empires varies across different systems or in the same regional system over time as new institutional developments emerge. We know that the development of new techniques of power, as well the integration of larger and larger regions into systems of interacting production and trade, facilitates the emergence of larger and larger polities as well as larger and larger cities. Thus there is a secular trend at the global level and within regions between city sizes and polity sizes over the past six millennia. But the question we are asking here is about finer temporal and spatial relationships. Do cities and empires rise and fall together? Are there important exceptions to this pattern? What are the causalities involved?

           

            We will further examine the relationship between power, urban growth and settlement size hierarchies by comparing trends in the growth/decline sequences of city populations and the territorial sizes of empires. Our units of analysis will be:

  1. Political/Military Networks (PMNs), otherwise called interstate systems;
  2. Constant Regions[3], in order to see how spatial boundaries might be related to patterns in the city-empire relationship; and
  3. Polities (states and empires), because the simplest form of the hypothesis of a causal relationship between power and urbanization is that larger states can afford to create larger cities.

And we will examine the temporal relations between the simple sizes of cities and empires, as well as size distributions of cities and the size of empires when data are available.

           

            Measurement of the population sizes of cities and the territorial sizes of empires is not without difficulties, especially for early periods. How can we know the number of people who reside in Los Angeles today? We use the most recent census, a survey of “residents” conducted by the U.S. federal government. What are the spatial boundaries of “Los Angeles”? Do we mean the city of Los Angeles, Los Angeles County, the contiguous built-up area that constitutes “greater Los Angeles,” or a definition based on the proportion of the local population that is employed in “Los Angeles”? Does “Los Angeles” include San Diego? Nighttime satellite photos of city lights reveal a single unbroken gigalopolis from Santa Barbara to Tijuana:

 

 

So where is Los Angeles? We want to use the contiguous built-up area as our main way of spatially defining cities. For early cities we do not have official, and ostensibly complete, census figures. Thus we rely on methods that archaeologists and students of early urbanization have developed to estimate the population sizes of cities.

These involve, for example, determining the spatial size of the city and then estimating the population density per unit of area and so estimating the total population. Population density varies depending upon the size of families, the nature of dwellings, the amount of non-residential area within settlements, and cultural differences. Anthropologists and archaeologists have made an important effort to produce reliable methods for estimating population sizes from residential areas (Brown 1987).

Tertius Chandler (1987) used reports about the number of soldiers to estimate city sizes, assuming that an army of men represents, on the average, about ten percent of the population of the city in which the army resides. Such estimates are obviously error-prone. Another problem with existing data on both city and empire sizes is that they were produced from surveys of both secondary and primary sources that are now, in many cases, obsolete because more recent and better research has been published by archaeologists, epigraphers and historians. Chandler’s compendium was mainly based on his thorough survey of the contents of the main library at the University of California, Berkeley over the four decades prior to its publication in 1987. A new project to improve upon Chandler’s compendium of city sizes is under way at the Institute for Research on World-Systems at the University of California, Riverside.

            Estimating the territorial sizes of empires is also problematic. Taagepera used atlases and maps to produce his estimates of the spatial sizes of empires from 3000 BCE to the present. But the boundaries of empires are not usually formally specified, but are rather a matter of degrees of control that fall off with distance from the central region. Archaeological evidence of the presence of a core culture in a peripheral region does not prove the existence of control, because many core polities have established colonial enclaves in distant peripheries to facilitate trade (e.g. Stein 1999). So the estimation of empire sizes is also fraught with difficulties. But, as with city sizes, a significant improvement of accuracy, temporal resolution and coverage would result from a renewed effort to code empire sizes using recently published materials. This is another task that the IROWS City-Empire Research Working Group will undertake.[4]

            Dating is also a major problem in studying temporal relationships in the ancient world-systems. In this paper we utilize the years originally supplied by Taagepera and Chandler. But the dating of events and city size estimations for the millennia BCE is a matter of continuing dispute among scholars of ancient history. For ancient Western Asia the Egyptian dynastic dates are used, but these have been repeatedly revised with an error margin of around 25 years. This is a threat to any study of temporal correlations.

 

Mesopotamia

The first PMN we shall examine is that of Mesopotamia from 2800 to 550 BCE. It is mistaken to speak of a single West Asian/North African world-system for this whole period. Rather two core areas – Egypt and Mesopotamia – were undergoing developmental processes that were only weakly linked, especially at first. As both of these systems expanded their trade networks and political/military interaction networks they came into contact with one another. The prestige goods nets (PGNs) became linked as early as 3000 BCE (Marfoe 1987) or as late as 2250 BCE (Wilkinson 1992), while the Mesopotamian and Egyptian political/military networks became linked by the Egyptian expedition to Syria (about 1520 BCE). We examine the relationship between the population size of the largest city and the territorial size of the largest state or empire in a region as these change over time. The hypothesis of a correspondence between urbanization and the size of polities should reveal a positive correlation in these two measures over time. The data on city population sizes are especially sparse for early millennia and the time points of estimates are widely spaced, making temporal correlation risky. For Mesopotamia our data set is thus:


 

Year (BCE)

Empire Size (square megameters x10)

Empire Name

City Size (thousands)

City Name

-2800

1

Kish

80

Uruk*

-2500

3

Kish

50

Uruk*

-2400

5

Lagash

 

 

-2300

65

Akkadian

36

Agade*#

-2200

25

Akkadian

 

 

-2100

3

Ur

 

 

-2000

10

Sumer

65

Ur

-1900

0

 

 

 

-1800

10

Old Assyria

29

Mari

-1700

25

Babylon

 

 

-1600

16.6

Babylon

60

Babylon

-1500

10

Kassite

 

 

-1450

10

Kassite

 

 

-1400

10

Kassite

 

 

-1360

21.7

Hittites

45

Khattushash (Hattusa)

-1350

5

Assyria

45

Khattushash (Hattusa)

-1300

10

Assyria

 

 

-1250

15

Assyria

 

 

-1200

25

Hittites

48

Khattushash (Hattusa)

-1150

5

Assyria

 

 

-1100

40

Assyria

 

 

-1050

15

Babylon

 

 

-1000

15

Babylon

51

Babylon

-950

15

Babylon

 

 

-900

15

Babylon

 

 

-850

40

Assyria

 

 

-800

57.9

Assyria

50

Calah

-750

40

Assyria

 

 

-700

90

Assyria

 

 

-650

93.3

Assyria

120

Nineveh

-600

25

Babylon

 

 

-550

50

Babylon

 

 

Table 1:Mesopotamian Largest Empires and Cities

*These estimates are from Modelski (1997). All other estimates are based on Chandler and Taagepera.

#Archaeologists have not yet decided which of the thousands of tells in Iraq is Agade, the capital of Sargon’s Akkadian empire. 

 

            Table 1 immediately demonstrates problems of missing data, especially for the third millennium. The time points for city sizes are far apart, and there are obviously missing cases. We have Modelski’s (1997) best estimate of the population size of Uruk in 2800 and 2500 BCE, but the largest empire shown in Taagepera’s data is that of Kish, a city-state that was independent of the much larger empire of Uruk in this period. This obvious error strongly demonstrates the need for upgrading the data sets we are using. In the data presented in Table 1 and in the figures and tables below we have interpolated Taagepera’s dates of changes in the sizes of empires to regular time intervals (every 50 years in Table 1 and Figures 1 and 2; every 10 years for the other regions in Table 2 and the figures in the Appendix).

            Another complication revealed in Table 1 and Figure 1 (below) is as follows: in 1350 and 1200 BCE the largest city is Khattushash (Hattusa), the capital of the Hittite empire, but the largest empire in the Mesopotamian region is the Neo-Assyrian Empire. This raises the issue of the proper unit of analysis – regions or polities – but it also raises a theoretical issue. The simplest version of the size-power hypothesis is that larger empires can afford larger cities, and to test this hypothesis we would need temporally fine-grained data on the size of the largest city within each empire. For this purpose the unit of analysis should be the polity (states and empires). But it may also be the case that regions or PMNs experience cyclical periods of growth and decline in which all the states and cities are growing, or alternatively that state and city growth is a zero-sum game in which growth in some results or is related to decline in others. By using and comparing different spatial units of analysis we can examine these competing hypotheses.

 

Figure 1: Largest Mesopotamian Cities and Empires

 

            The temporal relationship between the size of the largest city and the size of the largest empire is positive for the Mesopotamian case with a positive Pearson’s r correlation coefficient of .59 based on ten time points for which we have data for both variables. This supports the hypothesis of a causal relationship between these features of the social landscape, but the positive association could also be due to other factors or to the secular trending of these characteristics. We will return to these issues when we have more and better data in the cases to be discussed below.

 

Egypt

        As with Mesopotamia the data for Egypt are few and problematic. But using what we have produces the results displayed in Figure 2.

Figure 2: Largest Egyptian Cities and Empires

            The temporal relationship between city and empire sizes in Egypt is also positive, producing a Pearson’s r correlation coefficient of .52 based on seven time points on which we have data for both variables. Though there is a secular upward trend, both city and empire sizes also reveal decline phases and these are roughly synchronous with one another, though the few estimates of city sizes makes a firm conclusion risky.

 

Size and Power in Regions

            Table 2 presents the bivariate correlation coefficients between empire and city sizes for all of the regions for which we have sufficient data to study in this way. It also presents the partial correlations controlling for year to remove the long-term upward trend between city and empire sizes. The Americas and Africa do not have enough city size data, though this deficiency could and should be remedied by a new coding project.

Regional correlations between city and empire sizes

 

 

 

Region

Pearson’s r

Partial Pearson's r

# of time points

Years

 

Egypt

     0.216

     0.160

10

2300 B.C.E. - 550 B.C.E.

 

Mesopotamia

     0.784*

     0.763*

8

2800 B.C.E. - 550 B.C.E.

 

East Asia

     0.473**

     0.122

30

1360 B.C.E. - 1800 C.E.

 

Europe

     0.892**

     0.876**

24

430 B.C.E. - 1800 C.E.

 

South Asia

     0.286

     0.126

15

600 C.E. - 1800 C.E.

 

West Asia

     0.636**

     0.562**

27

2000 B.C.E. - 1500 C.E.

*

significant at the 0.05 level.

 

 

 

 

**

significant at the 0.01 level.

 

 

 

 

Table 2: Regional correlations between city and empire sizes

            Table 2 shows that four of the six regions have significant positive bivariate correlations between city and empire sizes (Column 2). This lends support to the contentions discussed above of a causal interaction between power and size, but these correlations do not shed light on the question of the direction of the causal effects. Once we have improved data we plan to employ the test of antecedence to shed light on this.

 

            One problem with the results in the Column Two of Table 2 is that the positive correlations may be due to the secular trends rather than to medium-term oscillations. Both city and empire sizes increase over time.[5]

 

In order to remove the effects of the secular upward trend we could use two different methods. The first is to compute partial correlations controlling for year. This is what we have done in Table 2 and the results are in Column Three. Another method of detrending would compute first differences, the change scores from one period to the next. The irregular time points of the early city size data make change score detrending messy, so this should only be done after more regular intervals of measurement have been established.

 

The detrended partial correlations in Column Three of Table 2 show that there are important differences among regions with respect to the relationship between city and empire sizes. The main difference between the bivariate and detrended partial correlations in in the East Asian region. The rather substantial and statistically significant bivariate correlation of .47 drops to .12 when the long-term trend is taken out. The result is that only three of the six regions continue to show a statistically significant positive relationship between empire and city sizes after detrending. The South Asian correlation also decreased but it was already low and insignificant. So Mesopotamia, Europe and West Asia show a rather substantial relationship between size and power, but South Asia, East Asia and Egypt do not. 

 

            We also need to do the same analysis for the other units of comparison – PMNs and individual empires. And indeed we also will present results for the correlations of size distributions, as well as correlations between the largest and second largest cities and empires.

 

            At present we are undertaking an analysis of the power-size relationship within individual polities, including the modern colonial empires. We will also examine the relationships among size distributions of cities and polities, and correlations between the sizes of largest and second largest cities and empires to examine the question of zero-sum vs. regional booms. Earlier work already has shown that empires tend to grow contemporaneously – periods in which the largest empire is growing tend also to be periods in which the second largest empire in growing in the same region. This would seem to be counter intuitive, and bears further examination of both empire and city growth decline sequences.

           

            We may also ask whether or not the causal relations stable over time within regions? We expect that there may be periodic changes in the relationship between power and size as new institutions develop. The rise of capitalism as an alternative source of power to military might and changes in the relationship between military power and demographic factors most likely change the nature of the connections between size and power. We know that empires ceased to increase in territorially size with the demise of the modern colonial empires. And the contemporary world city system may be unique in the extent to which some of the largest cities are located in the semiperiphery rather than in the core. These observations suggest that we should try to overcome the difficulties encountered in studying the last two centuries in order to shed more light on the power-size relationship.

 

            This working paper is part of a collaborative project that seeks to study the processes of social evolution and historical development by comparing regional systems, and by studying changes in institutional characteristics over long periods of time. The Institute for Research on World-Systems at the University of California, Riverside is beginning the process of upgrading the earlier coding of city and empire sizes by Chandler and Taagepera. We are working in interdisciplinary collaboration with a group of scholars associated with the World Historical Systems subsection of the International Political Economy Section of the International Studies Association.

 

Appendix: (the following figures are not perfectly accurate with respect to the data included in Table 2. The are presented only for purposes of rough comparison.)

 

References

 

Abu-Lughod, Janet Lippman 1989. Before European Hegemony:The World System A.D. 1250-1350

New York: Oxford University Press.

Algaze, Guillermo 1993 The Uruk World System: The Dynamics of Expansion of Early

Mesopotamian Civilization Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Allen, Mitchell J. 1997 “Contested peripheries: Philistia in the Neo-Assyrian World-System”

PhD dissertation, Department of Archaeology, University of California, Los Angeles

Barfield, Thomas J. 1989 The Perilous Frontier: Nomadic Empires and China. Cambridge, MA.:

Blackwell

Bosworth, Andrew 2000 "The evolution of the world city system, 3000 BCE to AD 2000"

Pp. 273-284 in Robert A. Denemark et al  (eds. ) World System History.  London:

Routledge.

Brown, Barton M. 1987 “Population estimation from floor area,” Behavior Science Research

21:1-49.

Chandler, Tertius 1987 Four Thousand Years of Urban Growth: An Historical Census.

Lewiston,N.Y.: Edwin Mellon Press

Chase-Dunn, Christopher 1985 "The system of world cities: A.D. 800-1975." Pp. 269-292 in

Michael Timberlake (ed.) Urbanization in the World-Economy, New York:Academic

Press.

______ 1992 "The changing role of cities in world-systems." Pp. 51-88 in Volker Bornschier

and Peter Lengyel (eds.) Waves, Formations and Values in the World System World Society

Studies, Volume 2, New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Publishers.

__________ 1995 “ Simultaneities of world-system development: cities, empires and climate

change.”  An unfunded proposal submitted to the National Science Foundation.

http://csf.colorado.edu/wsystems/archive/papers/c-d&hall/prop5/prop5.htm

Chase-Dunn, C and Thomas D. Hall 1997 Rise and Demise: Comparing World-Systems Boulder,

CO.: Westview Press.

___________ 2001 “City and Empire Growth/Decline Sequences in Ancient

Mesopotamian and Egyptian World-Systems” A paper presented at the annual

meetings of the International Studies Association, Chicago, February 24.

Chase-Dunn, C. , Susan Manning and Thomas D. Hall 2000 “Rise and fall: East-West

synchronicity and Indic exceptionalism reexamined,” Social Science History 24,4:727-

754.

Chase-Dunn, C.  and Alice Willard 1993 "Systems of cities and world-systems: settlement

size hierarchies and cycles of political centralization, 2000 BC-1988AD" A paper

presented at the International Studies Association meeting, March 24-27, Acapulco.

http://www.jhu.edu:80/~soc/pcid/papers/17/pcidpap17.htm

Chaudhuri, K.N. 1985 Trade and Civilisation in the Indian Ocean: An Economic History from the Rise

of Islam to 1750. Cambridge: University of Cambridge Press.

Chi, Ch'ao-ting 1963 [1935] Key Economic Areas In Chinese History: As Revealed in the Development

of Public Works for Water-Control, New York: Paragon Books.

Cioffi-Revilla, Claudio 1991 "The long-range analysis of war," Journal of Interdisciplinary History

21:603-29.

Collins, Randall 1992 "The geographical and economic world-systems of kinship-based and

agrarian-coercive societies." Review 15,3:373-88 (Summer). Westport, CT.:

Eckhardt, William 1992 Civilizations, Empires and Wars: A quantitative history of war    Jefferson, NC: McFarland.

Feinman, Gary M. and J. Marcus (eds.) 1998 Archaic States. Santa Fe: School of

American Research.

Fitzpatrick, John 1992 "The Middle Kingdom, the Middle Sea and the geographical pivot of

history." Review 15,3:477-522 (Summer).

Frank, Andre Gunder 1992 "The Centrality of Central Asia" Comparative Asian Studies

Number 8.

________ 1993 “The bronze age world system and its cycles.” Current

Anthropology 34:383-413.

______ 1998 Reorient:: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley: University of California

Press.

Frank, Andre Gunder and Barry Gills 1994 The World System: 500 or 5000 Years? London:

Routledge.

 Kowalewski, Stephen A. 1982 "The evolution of primate regional systems" Comparative

Urban Research 9,1:60-78.

Lattimore, Owen 1940 Inner Asian Frontiers of China. New York: American Geographical

Society.

Mann, Michael 1986 The Sources of Social Power: A History of Power from the Beginning to A.D.

1760. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Marcus, Joyce 1999 “The peaks and valleys of ancient states.” Pp. 59-94 in G. Feinman

and J. Marcus (eds.) Archaic States. Santa Fe, NM: School of American

Research.

Marfoe, Leon 1987 "Cedar forest and silver mountain: social change and the development of long-distance trade in early Near Eastern societies," Pp. 25-35 in M. Rowlands et al Centre and Periphery in the Ancient World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

McNeill, William H. 1976 Plagues and People Garden City, NJ: Anchor Books.

Modelski, George 1997 “Early world cities: extending the census to the fourth millennium,” Prepared for the annual meeting of the International Studies Association,Toronto, March 21

__________ 1999 “Ancient world cities 4000-1000 BC: centre/hinterland in the world system.”  Global Society 13,4:383-392.

Modelski, George and William R. Thompson 1994 Leading Sectors and World Powers: The

Coevolution of Global Economics and Politics. Columbia, S.C.: University of South Carolina

Press.

Nissen, Hans J. 1988 The Early History of the Ancient Near East, 9000-2000 BC Chicago:

University of Chicago Press.

Sanderson, Stephen K. (ed.) 1995 Civilizations and World Systems. Walnut Creek, CA Altamira.

Schneider, Jane 1991 "Was there a pre-capitalist world-system?" Pp. 45-66 in C. Chase-Dunn

and T.D. Hall (eds.) Core/Periphery Relations in Precapitalist Worlds. Boulder, CO.: Westview.

Shin, Kyoung-Ho and Michael Timberlake 1999 “The global city network, 1977-97” A paper

to be presented at the annual meeting of the American Sociological Association,

Chicago, August 10.

Smith, David A. and Michael Timberlake 1995 “Conceptualizing and mapping the structure

of the world system’s city system,” Urban Studies 32,2:287-302.

Stein, Gil J. 1999 Rethinking World-Systems: Diasporas, Colonies  and Interaction in

      Uruk Mesopotamia. Tucson: University of Arizona Press.

Taagepera, Rein 1978a "Size and duration of empires: systematics of size" Social Science

Research 7:108-27.

______ 1978b "Size and duration of empires: growth-decline curves, 3000 to 600 B.C."

Social Science Research, 7 :180-96.

______1979 "Size and duration of empires: growth-decline curves, 600 B.C. to 600 A.D."

Social Science History 3,3-4:115-38.

_______1997 “Expansion and contraction patterns of large polities: context for Russia.”

International Studies Quarterly 41,3:475-504.

Teggart, Frederick J. 1939 Rome and China: A Study of Correlations in Historical Events Berkeley:

University of California Press.

Walters, Pamela Barnhouse 1985 "Systems of cities and urban primacy: problems of

definition and measurement." Pp.63-86 in Michael Timberlake (ed.) Urbanization in

the World-Economy, New York: Academic Press. 

 

Wilkinson, David 1987 "Central Civilization." Comparative Civilizations Review 17:31-59.

______1991 "Core, peripheries and civilizations." Pp. 113-166 in Christopher Chase-Dunn

and Thomas D. Hall (eds.) Core/Periphery Relations in Precapitalist Worlds, Boulder, CO.:

Westview.

______1992a "Decline phases in civilizations, regions and oikumenes." A paper presented at

the annual meetings of the International Studies Association, Atlanta, GA. April 1-4.

 ______ 1992b "Cities, civilizations and oikumenes:I." Comparative Civilizations Review 27:51-

87 (Fall).

_______ 1993 “Cities, civilizations and oikumenes:II” Comparative Civilizations Review 28

 

           



[1] Chase-Dunn and Hall (1997) propose a nested network approach to the spatial bounding of world-systems that includes (in order of ascending size) bulk goods nets (BGNs), political/military nets (PMNs), prestige goods nets (PGNs) and information nets (INs).

[2] In order to indicate our sympathy with the efforts of world historians to escape from Eurocentrism, we employ the conventions BCE (before common era) and CE (common era) to delineate time. 

[3]  The regions we will study are:

  1. Europe, including the Mediterranean and Aegean islands, that part of the Eurasian continent to the west of the Caucasus Mountains, but not Asia Minor (now Turkey);
  2. Africa;
  3. West Asia including Asia Minor, Mesopotamia, Syria, Persia, the Levant, and Bactria (Afghanistan).
  4. South Asia including the Indus river valley;
  5. East Asia, including China, Korea and Japan and Southeast Asia, but not Indonesia;

 

 

[4] See http://irows.ucr.edu/research/citemp/citemp.htm

[5] Indeed the recent sharp upturn in city sizes since 1800 CE is the reason why we end our analyses in that year. Including the years after 1800 would dwarf variation in earlier periods.This could be remedied statistically by logging the city population sizes.