1

 

 

 

 

      Conceptualizing Core/Periphery Hierarchies

                 for Comparative Study

 

 

       Christopher Chase-Dunn and Thomas D. Hall

 

 

 

 

 

 

The objectives of this chapter are to clarify

basic concepts for the comparative study of

world-systems and to explicate general propo-

sitions about the nature and role of

core/periphery hierarchies in historical

social change.  It is now widely accepted that

contemporary social change within national

societies is importantly conditioned by the

linkages and structural aspects of a global

stratified intersocietal network composed of

"developed" national societies in core re-

gions, "less developed" peripheral nations,

and intermediate semiperipheral countries.

Both historical analysis and formal (quantita-

tive) crossnational research have demonstrated

this (Wallerstein, 1974; Meyer and Hannan,

1979; Bornschier and Chase-Dunn, 1985).  But

in order to understand the basic structural

features and system logic of the contemporary

global socio-economic system it is desirable

to be able to compare it with intersocietal

networks which are structurally different.

And in order to know how system logic changes

(and thus to have insights about how the

contemporary system logic might be transformed

in the future) it is desirable to study how

the logics  of world-systems have become

transformed in the past.  Archaeologists and

historians have begun to consider the rele-

vance of core/periphery hierarchies for the

evolution of earlier, smaller regional socio-

economic systems, but few of these recent

studies are explicitly comparative, and confu-

sion about basic concepts undermines the value

of even the implicit comparisons which have

been made.

   We propose to clarify concepts for compara-

tive study and to put forth several hypotheses

about core/periphery hierarchies.  Concept

formation involves both deduction and induc-

tion.  Since existing concepts about

core/periphery hierarchies have been developed

primarily from studies of the modern world-

system, they need to be modified for compara-

tive use in a study of earlier and very dif-

ferent intersocietal hierarchies.  It is

important to avoid the mistake of simply

imposing vocabularies developed to explain the

modern system on earlier systems in ways which

distort analysis.  Our goal is to formulate

concepts and propositions in a way which

allows us to understand both similarities and

differences among core/periphery hierarchies

in stateless, state-based and capitalist

world-systems.

   This investigation is relevant for macroso-

ciological theories of social change, histori-

cal development, and evolution.  It has become

rather well-accepted that the development of

both modern and ancient societies has been

importantly conditioned by the existence of

larger intersocietal networks of exchange and

interaction (e.g., Mann, 1986).  There are

important controversies over how to conceptu-

alize and bound these larger systems.  The

strongest world-system position claims that

there is usually an explicit boundedness to

the larger intersocietal network, and that it

is this larger unit which displays system

logic and the dynamic processes which affect

the historical development of societies.  In

other words it is world-systems which develop,

not societies, and these are distinctly bound-

ed units.  A looser version simply acknowledg-

es the importance of intersocietal interac-

tions but does not assume that a particular

larger unit is the determinant unit which

develops or evolves.  One of the main goals of

future comparative research should be the

evaluation of the fruitfulness of various

formulations regarding the conceptualization

and bounding of world-systems and their gener-

al effects on societal development.

 

 

What Are World-Systems?

 

 

   Immanuel Wallerstein (1974, 1979) defines a

world-system as an entity with a single divi-

sion of labor and multiple cultures, and

within this category there are two sub-types:

world-empires in which the intersocietal

division of labor is encompassed by a single

overarching imperial polity, and world-econo-

mies in which the political system is composed

of many states competing with one another

within an interstate system.  Wallerstein

excludes the analysis of stateless societies

by characterizing them as "mini-systems" in

which, allegedly, production of basic subsis-

tence goods is accomplished within a single

cultural entity.  The intent of Wallerstein's

definition is to encompass those processes

which are substantially important for the

reproduction and historical development of

social structures.

   Our definition of world-systems has the

same intent, but it is somewhat more general

in order to facilitate the comparison of very

different intersocietal networks.  We define

world-systems as intersocietal networks in

which the interaction (trade, warfare, inter-

marriage, etc.) is an important condition of

the reproduction of the internal structures of

the composite units and importantly affects

changes which occur in these local structures.

 

 

   One of the most important structural fea-

tures of the contemporary global intersocietal

system is the stratified set of relations of

dominance and dependence between the "devel-

oped" and "developing" countries.  The study

of the mechanisms which reproduce internation-

al inequalities is a burgeoning field in

cross-national comparative research (see

review in Chase-Dunn, 1989: Chapter 11).  The

concepts of core, periphery and semiperiphery

have been developed in studies of the modern

world-system.  Some scholars have begun the

task of studying intersocietal hierarchies in

earlier world-systems, but the conceptualiza-

tions being used are often confused and con-

fusing.  What is needed is an explicit effort

to formulate competing notions of coreness and

peripherality with an eye to a comparative

study of intersocietal inequalities.  It is

certain that there have been intersocietal

hierarchies in the past which operated in ways

very different from that of the contemporary

global relationship between "developed" and

"developing" countries.

   In the following we have taken a variation-

maximizing approach to the study of intersoci-

etal inequalities in order to explore both the

general similarities and the important diver-

gences among different sorts of world-systems.

We have been stimulated to search for differ-

ences by the very provocative general argu-

ments made by Ekholm (1980) and Ekholm and

Friedman (1982).  They argue that all state-

based world-systems can be characterized as

operating according to a logic of "capital

imperialism" in which core regions accumulate

resources by exploiting peripheral regions.

They also contend that conflicts within and

between core societies are the primary factors

which account for the demise of old cores and

the rise of new ones.  These general argu-

ments, which are said to apply to both ancient

world-systems and the modern world-system,

require evaluation by means of systematic

comparison of different world-systems.  We

have developed the hypotheses outlined below

in order to elaborate possible differences,

but we are also quite interested in the extent

to which state-based and capitalist intersoci-

etal systems share certain general features.

   It should not be assumed, however, that all

intersocietal systems have core/periphery

hierarchies.  We can certainly imagine hypo-

thetical world-systems without intersocietal

inequalities or exploitation.  Indeed, most

orthodox theories of modern international

trade assume equal exchange.  The existence of

exploitation, domination or equal exchange

should not be a matter of assumption, but

rather of investigation.  We suspect that some

stateless intersocietal systems did not have

core/periphery hierarchies, while others had

only mild and episodic ones.  In order to

understand the conditions which generate

intersocietal inequalities it is necessary to

examine cases in which they are absent.

   In what follows we will outline our concep-

tualizations of world-system boundaries,

core/periphery hierarchies and a qualitative

typology of very different intersocietal

systems.  Then we will propose several hypoth-

eses regarding the presence, nature and func-

tioning of core/periphery hierarchies in

different types of world-systems. 

 

 

 

 

World-System Boundaries

 

 

In order to study world-systems comparatively

we must conceptualize the spatial boundaries

of such systems in a way which allows very

different kinds of intersocietal networks to

be compared to the modern global political

economy.  It is commonplace that everything in

the universe is in some way connected or

related to everything else.  But if we are in

the business of formulating and testing scien-

tific theories of human historical develop-

ment, it is desirable to concentrate on those

types of interconnection which are most impor-

tant to the reproduction and transformation of

political and socio-economic structures.

Lenski and Lenski (1987: 51) refer to a single

"world system of societies" as existing "thro-

ughout history." The number and sizes of

world-systems are, of course, a function of

the way in which we define the connections

which count.  As Lenski and Lenski (1987) say:

 

 

   Throughout history, human societies have

   established and maintained relations

   with one another.... During much of the

   past direct ties were limited to neigh-

   boring societies, since direct relations

   with distant societies were not possi-

   ble.  But, even then, indirect relations

   existed.  Society A maintained ties with

   Society B, which in turn, maintained

   ties with Society C, and so on through-

   out the system.  No society was ever

   totally cut off from the world system of

   societies for long, since even the most

   isolated societies had occasional con-

   tacts with others.  With advances in

   transportation and communication during

   the last five thousand years, relations

   between societies have increased greatly

   and direct relations have been estab-

   lished between societies far removed

   from one another. As a result, the world

   system of societies has grown more inte-

   grated and more complex, and has come to

   exercise a greater influence on the life

   of individual societies (1987: 51).

 

 

   By almost any definition there has been a

global world-system since the end of the

nineteenth century.  Despite what the Lenskis

say, before that there were human intersoci-

etal networks which were substantially sepa-

rate and autonomous with regard to their

material and cultural processes of reproduc-

tion and development.  If we use trade, infor-

mation flows, political authority, or military

competition to define intersocietal system

boundaries, the human population of the Earth

has, over the last ten thousand years, gone

from a situation in which there were thousands

of small, substantially separate regional

intersocietal networks to the single global

network of today.

   There are a number of problems which are

encountered in all network analyses which need

clarification if we want to bound world-sys-

tems theoretically and empirically.  Differen-

tial interaction densities, nested structures,

direct and indirect connections, hierarchical

versus decentralized networks, levels of

hierarchy, multicentric hierarchies in which

the centers are either directly connected or

only indirectly connected through shared

peripheries -- these are all possible problems

in conceptualizing and empirically bounding

intersocietal networks.  And, in addition to

these complexities, the type of connection and

the institutional nature of interactions are

important.  Thus, even if we decide to focus

on material exchanges, it is important to know

what is being exchanged, and the institutional

nature of the exchange (gift, tribute, commod-

ity trade, etc.).

   Before designating an eclectic approach to

world-system boundaries we will review the

proposals of other scholars.  The shift of the

unit of analysis from societies to world-

systems encourages us to consider interconnec-

tions rather than uniformities as the impor-

tant features of boundedness.  Scholars who

have debated the best ways to bound "civiliza-

tions" (e.g., Melko and Scott, 1987) have

divided into those "culturalists" who stress

the homogeneity of central values as defining

civilizational boundaries, and those other

"structuralists" who use criteria of intercon-

nection rather than homogeneity.  Within the

group of interconnectionists there are several

possibilities.  Information flows have been

used by some archaeologists (e.g., Renfrew,

1977; Schortman and Urban, 1987) to bound

regional systems.  Most scholars, however,

employ either political/military or trade-

based interconnections.

   Immanuel Wallerstein (1974, 1979) uses two

different criteria when he bounds world-sys-

tems:  1. mode of production and, 2. trade in

bulk goods.  Mode of production is the struct-

uralist Marxist terminology for the system

logic of social structural reproduction,

competition and cooperation.  Thus capitalist,

tributary, socialist, and kin-based modes of

production are understood to be qualitatively

different system logics.  Wallerstein defines

capitalism as a feature of the modern world-

system as a whole.  By this theoretical maneu-

ver he incorporates peripheral capitalism into

the capitalist mode of production, a decided

advance over those who see the periphery of

the modern world-system as exhibiting precapi-

talist modes of production.  An unfortunate

corollary of this "totality assumption" is

that each world-system can have only one mode

of production, and thus it is not possible for

different modes to be articulated within a

single world-system.  Hence, according to

Wallerstein (1989, Chapter 3), the Ottoman

Empire was a separate system from the European

world-system until it had been entirely perip-

heralized by the European powers in the nine-

teenth century, because capitalism was not the

dominant mode of production in the Ottoman

Empire.  This requires defining the obviously

important economic and political/military

interactions between the Ottomans and the

European powers over several centuries as

epiphenomenal.

   The other criterion used by Wallerstein is

the network of exchange of basic goods --

everyday raw materials and foodstuffs.  He

argues that networks of the production, dis-

tribution and consumption of these basic goods

unite people across societal boundaries and

create the systemic unity of a world-system.

In the modern world-system (the "capitalist

world-economy") these forward and backward

linkages are called "commodity chains," but

Wallerstein's usage suggests that non-commodi-

fied exchange of material basic goods may also

be understood as constituting the interconnec-

tions of world-systems in which commodified

trade is nonexistent or little developed. 

   Chase-Dunn (1989: Chapters 1, 16) has

argued that Wallerstein's totality assumption

is a theoretical mistake which makes the

empirical bounding of world-systems in space

nearly impossible.  This is because we do not

have clear conceptualizations of how modes of

production are related to the spatial distri-

bution of human activities.  Chase-Dunn also

argues that the totality assumption makes the

study of the ways in which modes of production

become dominant within world-systems, and are

transformed into qualitatively different

system logics, nearly impossible.  If, by

definition, each world-system has only one

mode of production, how can we describe and

study instances in which different logics are

contending with one another within a world-

system?  It is much preferable to define

world-system boundaries in terms of empirical-

ly ascertainable types of network interconnec-

tions and then to tackle the difficult ques-

tion of modes of production and their trans-

formation after this bounding has been done.

Wallerstein's second criterion (bulk goods

exchange) is more easily operationalized and

we will propose its use together with other

types of interconnection.

   Wallerstein differentiates between basic

goods and "preciosities" which are luxury

goods with a high ratio of value to weight.

He argues that preciosities are not important

to the reproduction or transformation of

social structures, but only to the rather

epiphenomenal aspects of elite life.  This

argument allows him to focus on the Europe-

centered system, and to treat India and China

(long linked to Europe by the long distance

trade in prestige goods) as "external arenas."

But Jane Schneider (Chapter 2 below) convin-

cingly argues that, as most anthropologists

have long known, the exchange of prestige

goods is not epiphenomenal at all.  Prestige

goods are often very important to the repro-

duction of local power structures as elites

use them to reward subalterns and to symbolize

power.  Imported bullion is used to sustain

the army of the king and to pay mercenaries,

and is thus important to maintaining and

changing state structures.

  On this basis Schneider argues that there

was a larger precapitalist Eurasian world-

system long before the emergence of an impor-

tant core region in Europe.  Janet Abu-Lugho-

d's (1989) book on the importance of thir-

teenth century interactions between Europe and

the older core areas of the Near East, India

and China adds valuable support to Schneider's

contentions.

   Other authors have argued that prestige

goods economies are not only important to the

reproduction of power in some world-systems

(e.g., Blanton and Feinman, 1984), but that

the process of state-formation in peripheral

areas is often facilitated when one lineage

monopolizes the import of core preciosities

(Webb, 1975).  Friedman and Rowlands (1977)

and Friedman (1982) have argued that prestige

goods economies are important in the processes

of the rise and fall of chiefdoms and the

emergence of primary states.  Even though bulk

goods networks typically have much smaller

spatial boundaries than networks of prestige

good exchange, a comparative study of world-

systems needs to examine both of these types

of material exchange.

   Fernand Braudel (l984), like Wallerstein,

developed his terminology in order to make

sense of the Europe-centered world-system.

Thus he considers commodity exchange and

"economic" trade to be the most important type

of interconnection.  He also thinks that

hegemony is best defined in terms of economic

domination, which is arguably the case for the

modern world-system, but is certainly debate-

able for earlier world-systems.  In world-

systems in which the tributary modes of pro-

duction have been dominant, socially struc-

tured inequalities, including those between an

imperial core and dominated peripheral re-

gions, were based more completely on politi-

cal/military power.  Braudel (1984: 27) de-

fined the boundaries of world-systems in terms

of the scope of economic hegemony of a single

city-state.  Thus he described world-systems

centered on Venice, Malacca, Genoa, Antwerp,

etc.  Defining a network in terms of a single

center precludes the possibility of multicen-

tric networks.  It is like treating the Brit-

ish Empire as a separate system from the

French Empire.  The reality is that these were

colonial empires within a larger multicentric

intersocietal system.  Many, if not most,

ancient world-systems were also multicentric

in the sense that either the core areas were

constituted as an interstate system of several

autonomous states, or there were a few large

empires interacting with one another.  The

thirteenth century Eurasian world-system

studied by Janet Abu-Lughod (1989) had three

separate core areas linked directly by long

distance prestige goods trade and indirectly

by interactions with shared peripheral re-

gions.  The notion of multicentricity should

not preclude us from studying the differential

extent of centralization within intersocietal

systems, but defining these systems in terms

of single centers is certainly a mistake.

   Two other explicit suggestions for bounding

world-systems have been made, both of which

focus on political/military interaction rather

than trade.  Charles Tilly (1984: 62) has

suggested the following "rule of thumb for

connectedness":

 

 

   the actions of powerholders in one re-

   gion of a network rapidly (say within a

   year) and visibly (say in changes actu-

   ally reported by nearby observers) af-

   fect the welfare of at least a signifi-

   cant minority (say a tenth) of the popu-

   lation in another region of the netork.

 

 

   Tilly's definition focuses on intentional

political authority which is popularly per-

ceived.  It addresses the problems of tempo-

ral and spatial cutting points which any

network approach must confront, and which also

needs to be clarified in the trade-based

definitions if they are to be operationalized.

Not addressed are problems of multicentricity

and indirect connections.  Are two spatially

distant kingdoms contending for domination in

an intermediate region part of the same system

or are they separate systems?

   Another approach is that taken by David

Wilkinson (1987).  Wilkinson bounds "civiliza-

tions/world-systems" by the criterion of

interaction through conflict, especially

military competition.  Thus two empires that

regularly engage each other in military con-

frontations are part of the same system.  By

this definition Wilkinson creates a spatio-

temporal map which depicts the incorporation

of fourteen "civilizations" into what he calls

"Central Civilization" (Wilkinson, 1987: 32).

Citing Simmel and Coser, Wilkinson writes:

 

 

   Conflict always integrates in a mildly

   significant way, in that the transaction

   of conflicting always creates a new

   social entity, the conflict itself.  But

   durable conflict also integrates more

   significantly, by creating a new social

   entity that contains the conflict but is

   not reducible to it, within which the

   conflict must be seen as occurring,

   which is often of a larger scale and

   longer-lived than the conflict that

   constituted it.  It is therefore legiti-

   mate, and it is indeed necessary, to

   posit the existence of a social system,

   a single social whole, even where we can

   find no evidence of that whole existence

   other than the protracted, recurrent or

   habitual fighting of a pair of belliger-

   ents.  Such continuing relations, howev-

   er hostile, between groups however dif-

   ferent,necessarily indicates that both

   are (were or have become) parts of some

   larger group or system.  (Wilkinson,

   1987: 34; emphasis in the original.)

 

 

   Because he focuses only on state-based

urbanized "civilizations" Wilkinson excludes

from consideration those intersocietal net-

works in which there are no states, but his

criterion could also be used to bound them.

For example, Raymond Kelly (1985) has studied

the ways in which habitual raiding between

Nuer and Dinka pastoralists reproduced their

kin-based social structures in a fascinating

instance of "tribal imperialism."  A compara-

tive study of core/periphery hierarchies

should include consideration of systems in

which there are no states or classes.

   Another approach to defining intersocietal

linkages has been formulated by Schortman and

Urban (1987).  Their review of the development

of theoretical perspectives in archaeology

provides valuable insights into the contribu-

tions of diffusionism, studies of accultura-

tion, ecological/evolutionism and world-system

approaches to intersocietal interactions.

They also review and evaluate the literature

of the last two decades on the archaeological

study of trade.  Their own theoretical formu-

lation of the problem of intersocietal linkag-

es focuses on the concept of information,

which is defined broadly as "energy, materi-

als, social institutions, and ideas" (Schort-

man and Urban, 1987: 68).  They point out that

the economic aspects of trade are only part of

intersocietal interaction, and they emphasize

ideological diffusion and, especially, "inter-

societal ethnic links" (marriages) among

elites involved in prestige goods economies.

The relevance of prestige goods economies has

already been discussed above, and Schortman

and Urban are undoubtedly correct to emphasize

the importance of the symbolic and cultural

aspects of trade for some intersocietal sys-

tems.  On the other hand, they completely

ignore the systemic aspects of military compe-

tition emphasized by Wilkinson.

   The problem of world-system boundaries

necessarily interacts with the question of the

theoretical conceptualization of

core/periphery hierarchies because it is

necessary to distinguish between peripheral

areas which are part of a system and regions

which are external.  The next section will

address this problem.  Here we want to propose

an eclectic approach to the definition of

world-system boundaries.

   We propose to combine some of the approach-

es discussed above.  It would be presumptuous

to argue that certain forms of interaction are

always causally more important for social

change, especially when we want to study

world-systems with very different sorts of

social institutions and developmental logics.

It is probable that the most important types

of network linkages vary across different

kinds of systems, but distinctions of that

kind should be the outcome of research rather

than the starting point.

   We propose to study both economic and

political forms of interaction as features of

world-system networks.  All material exchanges

will be considered, although the patterns of

different kinds of trade good networks will

undoubtedly produce very different networks.

It will undoubtedly be necessary to consider

how localized networks of basic goods exchange

are linked into larger networks of prestige

goods exchange.

   We will also utilize the criterion of

political-military conflict inter-

action proposed by Wilkinson. Again, this will

undoubtedly produce networks with different

boundaries, but it is best to use a broad and

eclectic approach rather than to exclude

elements a priori.  Simplifications are desir-

able, but should be made on a basis informed

by empirical research.

 

 

The Subunit Problem

 

 

   Another problem which affects the conceptu-

alization and bounding of world-systems for

comparative study can be called the subunit

problem.  What are the subunits of which

world-systems are composed?  When we use the

term "intersocietal systems" this presumes

that the subunits are "societies," but much

recent analysis has stressed the difficulties

of bounding societies even within the modern

world-system composed primarily of nation-

states (e.g., Tilly, 1984).  Within the modern

world-system there are a few multinational

states, several states which govern only

portions of societies, many transnational

actors, and societal elements operating at the

international or even at the global level.

These problems are multiplied when we try to

compare world-systems of very different sizes

and kinds, especially "precapitalist" systems.

Wolf (1982) cautions that group boundaries are

inherently fuzzy and permeable.  It is impor-

tant to pay attention to the differing ways in

which subunit boundaries are formed and "tran-

ssocietal" interactions are constituted across

different types of world-systems.

   Urban and Schortman (1987) provide an

intelligent discussion of the subunit problem,

and they propose a solution which works fairly

well for some world-systems but not nearly as

well for others.  They define the subunits as

a "spatially delimited body of individuals

living within and adapting to a specific

physical environment" (1987: 63).  This type

of subunit, influenced by the ecologi-

cal/evolutionary framework, works well for

some smaller simpler systems, but it ignores

important larger subunits, such as states and

empires, which combine several types of eco-

logical niches within their boundaries.  The

way out of this problem is simply to recognize

that the sizes and types of organizations

which interact within regional world-systems

vary, and larger systems have increasingly

nested and overlapping levels of organization.

In the simplest intergroup systems, households

are politically organized at the village or

intervillage level, and there are no larger

overarching political organizations.  House-

holds and villages are important subunits in

all world-systems, large and small.  One

important difference between smaller regional

world-systems and larger, more complex world-

systems is the size of polities and the range

of direct economic, military and cultural

interactions.  It is not necessary to define a

single type of subunit which is common to all

world-systems, but rather to pay attention to

the types and levels of organization within

each whole world-system.

   The search for bounded world-systems also

must address the problem of direct and indi-

rect links.  Lenski and Lenski (1987) are

correct in saying that all human groups inter-

act fairly regularly and in important ways

with immediately neighboring groups.  This

means that almost all groups are indirectly

connected to all other groups.  Only impas-

sable physical barriers produce separate

networks if we allow very indirect connections

to count.  This still produces a rather large

number of substantially separate world-systems

before the advent of regularized oceanic

transportation.  But it would seem advisable

to utilize the criterion of the consequences

of events and actions to further restrict what

we consider to be significant indirect connec-

tions.  Thus, even though each precontact

California tribelet is connected to its neigh-

boring tribelets, and therefore indirect

connections extend North, East and South to

include the whole of the Americas, there is a

rather rapid fall-off in the impact that any

event will have. 

   What this means is that, when we are con-

sidering down-the-line interactions in which

a group interacts primarily with its immediate

neighbors, with few long distance direct

interactions, we will not find world-system

boundaries in the sense of lower density

interactions  except insofar as these are

created by natural barriers to interaction.

For these cases it makes sense to choose a

group or a connected set of groups as the

focus of analysis and to use this "group-

centric" focus to determine the boundaries of

the relevant interactional network.  For

example, we can focus on the Pomo and study

their world-system in the sense of the rele-

vant intergroup interactions.  We could just

as easily focus on a different group, and then

the "bounds" of the world-system would shift.

This kind of "group-centric" approach is

unfortunate in some ways because it would be

more desirable to allow the bounds of the

analysis to be determined by world-system

wholes rather than by focal societies.

   For the case of down-the-line types of

interaction this seems the only solution.

Once longer distance direct interactions

become important and world-systems networks

develop hierarchical and centric patterns,

these reduce the difficulty encountered here,

but do not eliminate it.  What are we to say

about the world-system of a village that is on

the periphery of two core regions which are

not directly connected to one another?  We do

not want to have as many world-systems as

there are possible focal societies, and yet it

is empirically the case that each group's

insertion into one (or more) world-systems is

different.  The answer is to use whole world-

systems as the unit of analysis in all cases

in which this is possible because of longer

distance direct interactions and patterns of

centralization.  In many cases in which inter-

action is almost completely down-the-line, we

will need to employ the group-centric ap-

proach, though our choice of which group with

which to start may be somewhat arbitrary.

   This, in turn, raises another problem: the

boundaries and limits of group identities.

Wolf (1982: 6) claims that, "by endowing

nations, societies, or cultures with the

qualities of internally homogeneous and exter-

nally distinctive and bounded objects, we

create a model of the world as a global pool

hall in which the entities spin off each other

like so many hard and round billiard balls."

Rather, groups are often internally diversi-

fied, boundaries are permeable, and member-

ships fluid.  This is especially true of band

and horticultural societies.  It is important

in discussions of ethnicity to not assume that

ethnic phenomena are invariant over time and

space, but vary with context.  The linkages

between the variable nature of ethnic identi-

ties and the core/periphery hierarchy context

remain problematic.

   The operationalization of the multi-crite-

ria approach to world-system boundaries will,

of course, encounter different problems in

different contexts.  Archaeological evidence

can be used for some kinds of trade networks,

although perishable goods such as food tend to

leave only indirect traces in the archaeologi-

cal record.  Evidence of authority relations

and sustained military interaction is substan-

tially more dependent on written records,

although some archaeological evidence,  such

as the building of defensive walls and the

concentration of previously dispersed settle-

ments into larger defensible towns, is also

relevant.  Ethnographic evidence will certain-

ly be used, especially for nonliterate societ-

ies, but ethnographic evidence from stateless

societies long influenced by interaction with

state-based and market-integrated societies is

often a contaminated source for inferences

about original stateless world-systems.

 

 

 

 

Core/Periphery Relations

 

 

Considerable controversy still exists about

the best way to conceptualize coreness and

peripherality in the modern global political

economy (e.g., Arrighi and Drangel, 1986;

Chase-Dunn, 1989: Chapter 10).  This debate

has proceeded primarily with the modern global

system as its context.  The issues are some-

what different when we consider the compara-

tive study of core/periphery hierarchies

across different kinds of world-systems.  Here

we need a more general conceptualization which

can accommodate greater variation, and we need

to allow for the possibility that some world-

systems do not have core/periphery hierar-

chies.     

   Applying the notion of a core/periphery

hierarchy to other than the modern world-

system is itself somewhat controversial.  The

esteemed economic historian Paul Bairoch

(1986) has argued that premodern core/peri-

phery relations are relatively unimportant

because there were not, he claims, significant

differences in the level of living between the

populations of core and peripheral areas, at

least compared to the large gap which emerged

during the industrialization of the European

core.  Most historians of the ancient empires

would disagree with the statement that

core/periphery relations were unimportant, but

differential degrees of internal stratifica-

tion between core and peripheral societies may

indeed turn out to be an important difference

between the modern world-system and earlier

world-systems.  While in the modern world-

system there is typically less income inequal-

ity among households in core societies than in

peripheral societies, this relationship was

undoubtedly the reverse in many of the ancient

world-systems in which the core was an urban-

ized and class-stratified society while the

periphery contained less stratified groups of

pastoralists and horticulturalists.  The

examination of such patterns and consideration

of their role in processes of social change is

one of the most interesting aspects of the

comparative study of world-systems.

   We will define two types of core/periphery

relationships for the purposes of comparative

study.  The first will be called

core/periphery differentiation, in which

societies at different levels of complexity

and population density are in interaction with

each other within the same world-system as

defined above.

   The second type is core/periphery hierar-

chy, which will be understood to mean the

existence of political, economic or ideologi-

cal domination between different societies

within the same world-system.  This includes

political domination, extraction of resources

through raiding, taxation, tribute, and un-

equal economic exchange.  We are also inter-

ested in cultural definitions of superiori-

ty/inferiority and how these may interact with

more objective forms of exploitation and

domination.  These ideological aspects will

not, however, be employed in our definition of

core/periphery hierarchy.

   We designate two types of core/periphery

relations -- differentiation and hierarchy --

because we think it is mistaken to assume that

all relations among "more developed" and "less

developed" societies involve exploitation and

the processes of the development of underde-

velopment which are often found in the modern

world-system.  We need not assume that the

"more developed" society always exploits the

"less developed."  Indeed there may be cases

of the reverse, and cases in which domination

exists between societies at virtually the same

level of complexity and population density.

Thus we seek to analyze how differences in

societal size, complexity, technological

productivity and internal stratification are

related to intersocietal domination.  The

nature, longevity and consequences for social

change in both core and peripheral societies

of various kinds of intersocietal relations

are the findings which comparative study is

intended to produce.  Variations in the degree

to which core/periphery relations cause the

"development of underdevelopment" and the

factors which account for such differences are

considered below in the section on hypotheses.

   We have intentionally left out any consid-

eration of the nature of what is produced and

traded between cores and peripheries.  The

notion that coreness and peripherality in the

modern world-system is essentially constituted

around a division of labor in which the core

produces manufactured goods and the periphery

produces raw materials is itself quite contro-

versial (Chase-Dunn, 1989: Chapter 10) and it

is known that important reversals of this

relationship sometimes occurred within ancient

world-systems (e.g., Lamberg-Karlovsky, 1975;

Kohl, 1987b).  Nevertheless such differences

may be important foci of comparative investi-

gation.  This can best be pursued by not

building these distinctions into our defini-

tion of core/periphery relations.  Rather we

need to investigate in each case the linkages

between intersocietal differentiation and

core/periphery domination.

   The intersection between the problem of

world-system boundaries and core/periphery

hierarchy mentioned above is especially sa-

lient at the edge of the periphery.  Wallerst-

ein (1989: Chapter 3) argues that, for the

modern world-system, even though an area has

been plundered by a core power, it is not yet

incorporated and peripheralized until local

production has become integrally linked into

the "commodity chains" of the larger world-

system.  It has been often observed that

plunder preceded the development of coerced

production in both the ancient empires and the

Europe-centered world-system.  Indeed there

may have been systems, such as the Nuer-Dinka

case mentioned above, in which plunder was the

sole form of core/periphery interaction.  It

is better to consider the dynamics of such

cases rather than defining them out of court

at the beginning, and indeed this may provide

important insights into the institutional

requirements of more stable core/periphery

structures.  Thus we intend to use Wilkinson's

definition, which includes regularized plunder

as a form of linkage defining the boundaries

of a world-system.  By this definition West

Africa was incorporated into the Europe-cen-

tered world-system when slave raiding became

regularized, rather than, as Wallerstein would

have it, after the development of colonial

agriculture in Africa.  Economic exploitation

is a more stable form of exploitation than

plunder because it does not decimate the

peripheral society to the same extent that

plunder does.  It is not the case, however,

that precapitalist cores only extracted trib-

ute and left production processes untouched.

The Inkas completely reorganized production in

incorporated territories and relocated popula-

tions to new regions in which intensified

horticulture could be carried out.  A general

definition should accommodate various forms of

exploitation and examine their consequences

for social change in both the core and the

periphery.

   Hall's (1989: Chapter 2) reconceptualizat-

ion of the incorporation process for the

modern world-system expands the outer bound-

aries of the system to include military alli-

ances and "buffer zone" groups in the "contact

periphery." This corresponds to Wilkinson's

definition of regularized political/military

interaction, and will be very helpful for

understanding frontier relations in precapita-

list world-systems (e.g., Dyson, 1985).

   Clear conceptualization of core/periphery

relations allows us to be more specific about

the meaning of the semiperiphery concept.  As

with coreness and peripherality, the defini-

tion of the semiperiphery remains controver-

sial even within the modern world-system (see

Chase-Dunn, 1989: Chapter 10).  At this point

we advocate that the semiperiphery concept be

defined broadly to encompass all of the fol-

lowing meanings:

1. A semiperipheral region may be one which

mixes both core and           peripheral forms of

organization.

2. A semiperipheral region may be spatially

located between core and            peripheral

regions.

3. Mediating activities between core and

peripheral areas may be carried           out in

semiperipheral regions.

4. A semiperipheral area may be one in which

institutional features are in             some ways

intermediate between those forms found in core

and   periphery.

   Sorting out these different types of semip-

eripheries remains an empirical as well as

theoretical problem.  Until more detailed

comparisons among different kinds of world-

systems are completed, it would be premature

to define the semiperiphery concept more

narrowly. 

 

 

 

A Typology of World-Systems

 

 

In order to achieve maximum variation in the

nature of world-systems we have developed a

preliminary typology based on distinctions

found in the literature on social evolution

and historical development (see review by

Moseley and Wallerstein, 1978).  These catego-

ries are not conceived as fixed boxes into

which a complex set of intersocietal networks

must be stuffed, but rather as a set of gener-

al signposts for the task of maximizing varia-

tion across the diversity of human societies.

   The central theoretical distinction we will

use in studying system logic is the neo-Marx-

ian notion of mode of production as it has

been elaborated in the works of Eric Wolf

(1982) and Samir Amin (1980).  These scholars

outline three major types of societal logic by

which social labor is mobilized and resources

are distributed: the kin-based mode of produc-

tion; the tributary (state-based) mode, and

the capitalist mode.  Building on the work of

Marx, and adding insights generated by Karl

Polanyi's (1977) theoretical approach, these

authors define kin-based relations as norma-

tive regulation based on consensual defini-

tions of what exists and what is good.  No

societies are exclusively structured around

this kind of social control, but in some

societies, those without classes or states or

markets, kin-based mechanisms of control and

distribution are the dominant sources of

social cohesion.

   The tributary modes of production involve

the use of physical coercion to mobilize

labor.  A ruling class establishes control

over some essential social resource and then

uses this control to extract "surplus product"

from direct producers.  There are many differ-

ent institutional forms by which this is

accomplished.  Most historical societies in

which this form of integration is dominant mix

a variety of these forms (taxation, tribute,

serfdom, slavery, etc.) and also include

elements of both kin-based and market forms of

integration.  However, these latter are usual-

ly incorporated in ways which reinforce the

fundamentally coercive state-based logic of

the tributary mode.

   The capitalist mode of production is based

on the commodity form, the mediation of human

interaction by price-setting markets, and

market-like institutions.  The commodification

of goods, land, wealth and labor are never

complete within capitalist systems, but mar-

kets play a much greater role than in systems

dominated by other modes.  Aspects of other

modes continue to be found, but they generally

are complementary with the reproduction of

commodified relations.  Thus we want to dis-

tinguish between world-systems in which kin-

based, state-based and capitalist modes of

production are dominant.

   By utilizing these distinctions, we are in

no way endorsing a unilinear model of evolu-

tion.  We argue that historical development is

open-ended and that important bifurcations and

discontinuities of development, rapid trans-

formations, and instances of devolution are

normal characteristics of the historical

processes of social change (See Sanderson,

Chapter 5 below).  We wish to evaluate the

idea that world-systems, rather than societ-

ies, are the relevant units of analysis for

understanding these processes, but this does

not lead us to ignore the processes which

operate within societies.

   In order to study the processes and pat-

terns by which modes of production become

transformed, we make use of rough set of

world-system types based on social structural

distinctions.  We seek to understand how

core/periphery hierarchies may play a role in

the reproduction or transformation of modes of

production, and so we need to distinguish

between types of world-systems in which both

core/periphery relations and modes of produc-

tion vary.  We will propose a rough set of

categories which will allow us to search for

the relevant variation.  This approach is not

a replacement for the study of long sequences

of historical change in particular regions,

but is rather only a preliminary step for

mapping out the major empirical distinctions

between types of core/periphery relations.

   We propose the following list of world-

system types.  The typology indicates the

level of structural complexity characteristic

of the most complex societies within each

whole world-system:

 

 

I. Kin-based mode dominant

   A. Stateless, classless

      1. Semisedentary foragers, horticultural-

ists, pastoralists

      2. Big man systems

   B. Chiefdoms (classes but not true states)

II.   Tributary modes dominant (true states,

cities)

   A. Primary state-based world-systems (Lower

Mesopotamia, Egypt, Indus                 Valley,

Ganges Valley, China, Mexico, Peru)

   B. Primary empires in which a number of

previously autonomous states              have been

unified by conquest (Akkad, Old Kingdom Egypt,

      Magahda, Chou, Teotihuacan, Huari)

      C. Multicentered world-systems composed

of empires, states, and             peripheral

regions (Near East, India, China, Mesoamerica,

Peru)

   D. Commercializing state-based world-sys-

tems in which important aspects of commod-

ification have developed but the system is

still dominated by the logic of the tributary

modes (Near East, Indian Ocean, China)

III. Capitalist mode dominant

   A. the Europe-centered subsystem since the

sixteenth century

   B. the global modern world-system

  

   Under heading I above (kin-based mode

dominant) are included all those world-systems

in which none of the societies can be said to

have true states. A true state is defined

following Johnson and Earle (1987: 246) as

existing when a regionally organized society

has specialized regional institutions --

military and bureaucratic -- which perform the

tasks of control and management.  This is

distinguished from "complex chiefdoms" in the

degree to which specialized state organiza-

tions have developed.  Complex chiefdoms,

which are also large and stratified polities,

rely on generalized institutions for regional

coordination and control.  Chiefdoms are

distinguished from less stratified stateless

societies by the size of the polity, popula-

tion density, intensification  of production,

and, obviously, the degree of internal strati-

fication.  In true chiefdoms, the chief has

institutionalized access to substantial social

resources to back up his power which are

largely autonomous from the control of other

lineage heads.  In classless societies, in-

equalities of power, prestige and wealth are

based almost entirely on age and gender crite-

ria, while class formation involves the in-

creasing control over basic societal resources

(land, trade, etc.) by a noble class.  Such a

class can appropriate surplus product based on

the labor of direct producers.

   The smallest autonomous polities are nomad-

ic foraging bands.  We choose to begin our

analysis of world-systems with those more

sedentary foragers who live most of the year

in hamlets.  These largely sedentary groups

define communal territorial boundaries and

engage in regularized intergroup relations

which can be analyzed as composing a small

world-system of interdependent interaction.

As population density per land area increases,

foraging strategies become more diversified

and intensification of production occurs

(horticulture, pastoralism).  Big man systems

emerge where there are pressures to increase

coordination among groups, but these are not

sufficient to sustain a more stable leadership

hierarchy.

   The problem of the causal relationship

between primary state formation and class

formation has been the focus of a vociferous

debate among anthropologists (e.g., Service,

1975; Carneiro, 1970).  Most of the work done

on this problem has not explicitly taken

account of the fact the these processes oc-

curred within the context of core/periphery

relations.  Exceptions to this are the work of

Friedman and Rowlands (1977) and Gailey and

Patterson (1987, 1988).

   Within category II (tributary modes domi-

nant) there are a number of distinctions which

need to be explained.  Primary or pristine

states are those which develop without contact

with existing states.  States developing in

interaction with existing states are termed

secondary.  The same distinction can, of

course, be applied to empires, and we do so in

category IIB.  We argue that most primary

state-based world-systems were politically

structured as interstate systems of competing

city-states within a core region.  Secondary

multicentric empires are distinguished from

primary empires by the prior existence of

empires and often by the larger size of the

constituent empires. The commercializing

world-systems are distinguished from most

earlier systems by their size, and by the

increasing commodification of goods, land,

wealth and labor.  The use of money spread to

the day-to-day lives of common people with the

development of smaller standardized denomina-

tions of coins, and forms of credit and inter-

est became more developed.  Wage labor and

other semi-commodified forms of labor became

more common.  Price-setting markets and com-

modity production for sale became more wide-

spread within the political economy.  Within

empires, rulers became somewhat more sophisti-

cated about the way in which they taxed mer-

chants and commodity producers so as not to

kill the golden goose; and outside the bounds

of empires, in interstitial semiperipheral

regions, autonomous city-states controlled by

merchant and production capitalists created

and sustained market relations between empires

and peripheral regions.            

   The degree of commodification increased,

but unevenly and not in the same way in each

area.  There were spurts ahead and then either

devolution to subsistence feudalism or reas-

sertion of imperial control of the economy.

The coming to dominance of capitalism in a

core region was a tipping point which occurred

first in Europe, and then spread with the

assistance of the expanding European hegemony.

 

 

   We do not want the above categories to

generate a lot of dispute about which cases go

into which categories.  Obviously there are

many borderline cases for which it is diffi-

cult to decide.  A different approach would be

to analyze very long historical sequences

which include the transformations of the

social structural characteristics which we are

using to distinguish among categories.  This

would eliminate the problem of "transitional"

cases, and would focus attention on those

major transformations which ought to be the

main focus if we are ultimately trying to

understand how fundamental changes could occur

in our own time.  But we suggest that it makes

sense to first focus on the larger patterns of

association among different kinds of

core/periphery hierarchies and structural

features of societies within world-systems.

After these matters are mapped out, we can pay

more attention to the causal nature of pro-

cesses of reproduction and transformation.

 

 

 

 

 

 

Hypotheses

 

 

In this section we describe our preliminary

formulation of theoretical hypotheses about

variation in core/periphery hierarchies based

on our interpretation of several different

literatures:  all the recent studies which

have explicitly discussed the application of

world-system concepts to precapitalist sys-

tems; the literature on imperialism and

frontiers in the ancient world; the archaeolo-

gy of diffusion, trade and warfare; and ethno-

graphic studies of intersocietal relations.

Elsewhere Chase-Dunn (1989: Chapters 10 ,11)

has reviewed the theoretical and empirical

studies on the nature and causes of reproduc-

tion of the modern core/periphery hierarchy.

   The most general questions for a compara-

tive study of core/periphery relations are:

1. Do all world-systems have stable

core/periphery hierarchies?

2. Do the stability, magnitude and nature of

intersocietal inequalities vary           systemical-

ly with the types of societies which compose

world-systems?          What is the relationship

between core/periphery differentiation and

   core/periphery domination?

3. What are the relationships between the

dynamics of core/periphery          relations and

the reproduction/transformation of social

structures,       institutions and basic system

logics?

Here we discuss these broad questions and

formulate positive

hypotheses from them.

   First, the generalizations we make apply to

whole world-systems, and thus, whole systems

need to be studied to test them.  It is known

that there is usually considerable variation

across peripheral regions within each world-

system.  This is important and needs to be

taken into account.  In studies of particular

world-systems, differences between regions in

the nature of core/periphery relations are an

important consideration (e.g., Dyson, 1985).

But for the general discussion of cross-system

comparisons, we will be talking about "aver-

age" or typical core/periphery relations

within each system.

   Obviously intersocietal networks in which

the constituent societies are all at about the

same level of complexity do not have

core/periphery differentiation as defined

above.  But of more interest is the matter of

core/periphery hierarchies.  Do all world-

systems have stable core/periphery hierarchies

in the sense that some societies exploit or

dominate others?  This involves consideration

of the nature, degree, and longevity of inter-

societal exploitation and domination.  In

addition it is desirable to consider differen-

tial rates of development, "co-evolution," the

development of underdevelopment, and processes

effecting these.  Also of interest will be the

relative size of core, peripheral and semiper-

ipheral areas, and the nature of relations

among core societies and among peripheral

societies.

   Our first hypothesis is that stable rela-

tions of intersocietal domination are diffi-

cult to create and reproduce in the absence of

hierarchical social institutions within the

societies involved.  The development of inter-

nal stratification and forms of the state are

quite important in the stabilization and

reproduction of core/periphery exploitation.

Thus we predict that kin-based intersocietal

systems will have only minimal and short-lived

core/periphery hierarchies, and that the least

hierarchical of human societies, those of

chiefless foragers, will not have any regular-

ized intersocietal domination or exploitation.

 

 

   We expect that intersocietal exploitation

among most semi-sedentary foraging groups is

limited to episodic raiding and competition

over favorable natural sites.  War captive

slavery to be found among some of the more

hierarchical hunter-gatherers (e.g., the

Yurok) and some pastoralists (e.g., the Nuer)

is likely to be of a relatively mild kind

because slaves must be incorporated into

existing kinship networks in order to mobilize

their labor, and kinship networks usually

bestow rights as well as obligations. 

   An intermediate case between unstratified

and chiefdom-based world-systems is that of

the Nuer-Dinka relationships studied by Kelly

(1985).  The Nuer lacked strong and permanent

chiefs, but they did have three levels of

hierarchy among villages which enabled them to

form larger war bands than the neighboring

Dinka, who were similar pastoralists, but had

only two levels of intratribal hierarchy.

Thus the Nuer systematically raided the Dinka

for cattle and women, and expanded into Dinka

territory over a 150 year period.  Though the

Nuer were clearly exploiting the Dinka by

appropriating cattle and women, the limited

forms of hierarchy within the Nuer society

prevented this relationship from stabilizing

into a core/periphery hierarchy based on

exploitation of coerced labor in the periph-

ery.  The Dinka women taken as captives were

rapidly assimilated into Nuer kinship struc-

tures. 

   Kristiansen (1987) has studied local and

regional hierarchical relations among state-

less peoples in Scandinavia.  Though he uses

the terms core and periphery to describe these

relations, he characterizes them as based on

the "ritual superiority" of local centers over

hinterlands based on the control of prestige

goods.  Friedman and Rowlands (1977) have

argued that core/periphery structures based on

prestige goods economies are unstable and

subject to rapid spread effects because of

the ideological nature of the stratification

which is not backed up by military coercion or

more stringent dependencies on fundamental

goods.

   Our second hypothesis is that the stability

and exploitativeness of core/periphery hierar-

chies increases with the degree of stratifica-

tion within core societies and with the devel-

opment of certain "technologies of power,"

(Mann, 1986) which enable centralized empires

to extract taxes and tribute from peripheral

regions.

   We hypothesize that the very first "pris-

tine" states will be found to be more success-

ful at extracting resources from peripheral

areas than kin-based cores, but still not as

successful as later, more centralized, em-

pires.  Also the "co-evolutionary" spread

effects of development (Schortman and Urban,

1987; Renfrew and Cherry, 1986) by which new

centers emerge as a result of interaction with

the original core areas, will be relatively

strong compared to "underdeveloping" effects

because the techniques for concentrating and

sustaining resources in the core are less

developed than in later empires.

   Thus we are further predicting that

core/periphery hierarchies will be relatively

more stable, more hierarchical, and more

underdevelopmental for peripheral regions once

centralized empires have emerged.  The decen-

tralizing phase of the process of the rise and

fall of empire-centers will reverse this trend

somewhat, as increased local autonomy for

controllers of land slows the concentration of

resources in the center.

   The growth of market forms of exchange,

monetary systems, local and long-distance

market trade, etc. will again increase the

"spread" effects relative to the "backwash"

effects.  More sophisticated empires, in which

the state-based mode of production remains

dominant, learn to extract surplus from market

trade without smothering it.  In these in-

stances central empires which provide pacifi-

cation and guarantee trade routes will streng-

then spread effects. Commercialized states

also learn to control the disruptive aspects

of market relations and to deal effectively

with potentially threatening peripheries.

   The emerging dominance of capitalism in the

Europe-centered sub-system produced a

core/periphery hierarchy in which backwash

effects strongly outweighed spread effects and

the gap between core and periphery rapidly

increased.  However, technological change is

much faster and greater in both core and

periphery in the modern world-system because

of the historically unique effects of capital-

ism on incentives for revolutionizing technol-

ogy.  The gap produced is thus a relative one

in which peripheral areas do develop, but at

much slower rates than the core.

   Regarding the matter of core/periphery

relations and transformations of the mode of

production, Chase-Dunn (1989) has argued  that

capitalism as a system logic is buffered from

its own developmental contradictions by the

existence of a necessary and reproduced

core/periphery hierarchy.  This implies that

peripheral capitalism and core exploitation of

the periphery should be understood as a neces-

sary and constitutive part of the capitalist

mode of production.  The modern core/periphery

hierarchy acts to sustain the multicentric

structure of the core (the interstate system,

which is arguably necessary for capitalism)

and to disorganize those political forces

within core states that would try to transform

capitalism into socialism.  This last is

accomplished by sustaining national class

alliances between core labor and core capital,

cemented by intracore rivalry and peripheral

exploitation.

   Ancient core/periphery hierarchies, we

suggest research will show, were often central

to the reproduction of centralized state

apparati.  Keith Hopkins (1978) contends that

the Roman empire was a system which, like

capitalism, needed to expand in order to

survive.  But, unlike the capitalist world-

economy, its expansion was based on conquest,

the importation of booty and slaves, and the

distribution of land and dependent laborers to

a growing class of non-producers.  When the

empire reached a zero rate of return in terms

of spatial expansion it was no longer able to

provide the resources necessary to sustain its

growing overhead costs.  It then began to turn

in upon itself, and eventually it crumbled.

Hopkins's model, which is similar to the

analysis of Anderson (1974), sees the "barbar-

ian invasions" as exogenous shocks which

conjuncturally dismembered a state which was

already falling of its own contradictions.

But though Rome fell, the state-based mode of

production and the "Central Civilization"

(Wilkinson, 1987; see also Chapter 4) of which

Rome was but a part, did not.

   In other cases, such as China, the mode of

production was "tributary" in the sense that

coercive power was used to mobilize labor and

accumulation, but this accumulation was pri-

marily accomplished without exploitation of

peripheral regions.  In many of these cases

the periphery did importantly affect the core

by threatening border regions or by occasion-

ally conquering the core (e.g Barfield, 1989;

Hall, Chapter 7 below).  Whether as a source

of exploitable resources or military threats,

peripheral regions were often important to the

reproduction and transformation of social

structures within cores.

   Many semiperipheral regions have also

played important roles in large scale social

change.  We hypothesize that this is because

of the peculiar combination of forces and the

organizational opportunities of groups who are

"in the middle" of core/periphery hierarchies.

Semiperipheral regions, we argue, are unusual-

ly fertile zones for social innovation because

they can combine peripheral and core elements

in new ways, and they are less constrained by

core domination than are peripheral areas, and

less committed than older core regions to all

the institutional baggage which comes along

with core status.  Of course the particular

techniques used by upwardly mobile semiperiph-

eries vary depending on the nature of the

world-system in which they are operating.

Four types of semiperipheral development are

described in Chase-Dunn (1988):

1. conquest by semiperipheral marcher states;

2. extensive and intensive commodification by

semiperipheral capitalist city-           states;

3. the emerging global domination of the

Europe-centered sub-system,         which we argue

was semiperipheral in the larger Afroeurasian

world-      system; and

4. the rise and fall of hegemonic core states

within the Europe-centered          world-system.

   A combination of Gerschenkron's (1962) idea

of the "advantages of backwardness," Trotsky's

(1932) "laws of combined and uneven develop-

ment" and Service's (1971) "adaptation and

adaptivity" can be used to formulate general

and specific propositions about semiperipheral

development (see Chase-Dunn, 1988).

 

 

 

 

Measurement Problems

 

 

Even though it will undoubtedly be necessary

to operationalize the concepts of world-system

boundaries and core/periphery relations dif-

ferently for different cases, especially since

we have intentionally  chosen to pursue a

most-different systems strategy, the goal of

testing more general propositions requires us

to think about the possibilities of operation-

alizing concepts in ways that are helpful for

formal comparisons across cases.  Comparable

measures will be especially important for

future studies which seek to compare large

numbers of world-systems using the methods of

formal comparative research.

   The problem of comparable measures of

system boundaries is important because the way

in which cases are bounded could influence the

outcome of comparisons among cases.  The only

way to be sure that one has employed an ade-

quate definition of system boundaries is to

compare the results of comparative analyses

using competing definitions.

   It may be found that it is necessary to use

different empirical criteria for bounding

world-systems depending on the type of system

being analyzed. Though this would be somewhat

messy, it would not make the analytic compari-

son of very different world-systems impossi-

ble.  For the present we propose to use the

multidimensional eclectic conceptualization of

boundedness we have described above with

attention to the consequences of bounding

according to the different criteria.

   Testing the hypotheses about the operation

of core/periphery hierarchies requires, ideal-

ly, that we be able to determine comparatively

degrees of intersocietal exploitation and of

the stability of core/periphery hierarchies.

It would also be desirable to be able to

compare rates of intersocietal mobility, and

the relative balance of "spread" consequences

and "backwash" consequences for differential

rates of "development" between cores and

peripheries.  These operational problems have

not yet been resolved even for the contem-

porary global world-system.  Nevertheless, we

want to clearly designate the desiderata of a

more generally comparative research project so

that exploratory case studies can be undertak-

en with these purposes in mind.

   The problems of measuring differences in

the magnitude of inequalities across social

systems are well-known.  When the kinds of

resources which are socially valued differ and

the dimensions of inequality are structured in

completely different ways, statements about

relative degrees of overall inequality are

problematic.  This is just as true of interso-

cietal inequalities as of intrasocietal ones.

Though it is often possible to rank objects

within a system, such rank orderings do not

help with the question of the magnitude of

inequalities.  For this, interval or ratio

scale measurement is required.

   Nevertheless, rough estimations of differ-

ential magnitudes of intrasocietal inequali-

ties have been convincingly made by Lenski

(1966) across very different societal types

(e.g., hunter-gatherer, horticultural, agrari-

an and industrial).  We propose to make analo-

gous "guesstimates" of degrees of inequality

across very different core/periphery hierar-

chies.

   The problem of indicators of core/periphery

inequality has been considered by some archae-

ologists.  Often it is simply assumed that ar-

chaeological indicators of core/periphery

differentiation can be taken as evidence of

core/periphery hierarchy.  For example, the

existence of a settlement system in which

villages and towns are of substantially un-

equal population sizes may be interpreted as

indicating hierarchical interaction between

large and small settlements (e.g., Nissen,

1988).  But, as many archaeologists have

themselves recognized, differentiation can

exist without domination (e.g., Renfrew and

Cherry, 1986).  All exchange is not unequal

exchange.

   Looking for more direct archaeological

evidence for core/periphery domination is

challenging.  Lamberg-Karlovsky (1975) has

argued that the village of Tepe Yahya on the

Iranian plateau (where carved soapstone bowls

were manufactured and exported to the Sumerian

cities) must have been subjected to unequal

exchange because burials did not become richer

at Tepe Yahya over the long period during

which trade occurred.  This case contrasts

with many others in which involvement in

regional exchange networks did lead to in-

creased local stratification as indicated by

the emergence of richer burials (e.g., Marfoe,

1987).

   Such observations might be used to differ-

entiate between non-exploitative and exploit-

ative intersocietal interactions, and to study

the trajectory of interactions within particu-

lar world-systems.  This usage of mortuary

evidence, may, however, encounter grave prob-

lems.  Wealthier native Californians were

cremated, while the remains of poorer villag-

ers were buried.  In this case the appearance

of more elaborate burials could mean less

rather than greater local stratification.  And

of course there are other causes of changes in

burial practices besides the nature of inter-

societal interaction.

   Though archaeologists have made amazing

strides in the use of recoverable results to

develop indicators of the spatial structure

and the social form of exchange (see review by

Schortman and Urban, 1987: 49-55), archaeolog-

ical evidence alone is often quite problematic

for the kind of inferences we want to make.

This is why it is important to study cases for

which archaeological data can be combined with

historical documentary or ethnographic evi-

dence.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Conclusions

 

 

We have proposed a set of definitions and

hypotheses which allow the world-systems

perspective to be extended from its current

focus on the Europe-centered system to a

consideration of very different sorts of

intersocietal networks.  In doing this we

propose to use the primary analyses of ar-

chaeologists, historians and anthropologists

as raw materials for constructing a world-

system theory of very long-term social change.

The comparative strategy we propose will allow

us a new purchase on the study of system

transformation which may be of use for under-

standing and transforming our own global

political economy.

   By defining world-systems and

core/periphery hierarchies generally we hope

to be able to sort out the important similari-

ties and differences which ought to be the

explicit backdrop for understanding future

human possibilities. Everything is not differ-

ent now, and neither is everything the same.

In order to know which things are importantly

different and which things are importantly the

same, it will be helpful to have a systematic

theoretical framework for comparing world-

systems.  This approach does not require that

we belittle those who are studying contempo-

rary processes of political, economic and

social change.  Ultimately the very long run

comparisons will need to be combined with more

immediate studies in order to produce politi-

cally useful insights.

   The next order of business is a series of

exploratory case studies which explicitly

address the problems of concept formation and

comparable measurement which we have raised.

Ultimately we think that it would be desirable

to be able to compare rather large numbers of

world-systems in order to have greater certi-

tude regarding the hypotheses we have proposed

about core/periphery hierarchies.  But we also

recognize that the strategy of comparison

across world-systems needs to be supplemented

with studies of single world-systems over very

long periods of time.  This other strategy is

explicit in the approach taken in Gills and

Frank (Chapter 3) and Wilkinson (Chapter 4) in

this volume.  We see comparisons over time as

complementary to comparisons over space, and

we have made every effort to see that the

conceptualizations employed in both approaches

find common ground.

                         NOTES