C.  Chase-Dunn and Bruce Lerro, Social Change. Forthcoming from Allyn and Bacon.
Chapter 2: The Comparative World-Systems Approach
v.12-5-01 (6843 words)
This chapter explains the main ideas that are needed to compare social systems one to another.In order to see the patterns of social change we need to be able to compare small networks of societies with larger regional systems, and with the global system of today.This is because the spatial scale of important interactions has grown over the millennia as societies have gotten larger and long-distance transportation and communication became easier.The basic concepts of world-systems, polities, interaction networks, modes of accumulation, and core/periphery relations allow us to see and compare the architectures of rather different kinds of systems and to examine both the continuities as well as the important changes that have occurred with social evolution. We will also discuss the macro-micro link between these social institutions and the psychology of individuals. We will apply Lev Vygotsky’s theory of learning to the formation of the social self and discuss the three phases of abstract thinking.
World-Systems
World-systems are systems of societies (see Figure 2.1). Systemness means that these societies are interacting with one another in important ways – interactions are two-way, necessary, structured, regularized and reproductive. Systemic interconnectedness exists when interactions importantly influence the lives of people within societies, and are consequential for social continuity or social change.World-systems may not cover the entire surface of the planet. Some extend over only parts of the Earth. The word “world” refers to the importantly connected interaction networks in which people live, whether these are spatially small or large. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

Figure 2.1: A world-system is a system of societies

Only the modern world-system has become a global (Earth-wide) system composed of national societies and their states. It is a single economy composed of international trade and capital flows, transnational corporations that produce products on several continents, as well as all the economic transactions that occur within countries and at local levels.The whole world-system is more than just international relations. It is the whole system of human interactions. The world economy is all the economic interactions of all the people on Earth, not just international trade and investment.

The modern world-system is structured politically as an interstate system – a system of competing and allying states. Political Scientists commonly call this the international system, and it is the main focus of the field of International Relations. Some of these states are much more powerful than others, but the main organizational feature of the world political system is that it is multicentric. There is no world state. Rather there is a system of states. This is a fundamentally important feature of the modern system and of many earlier regional world-systems as well. 

When we discuss and compare different kinds of world-systems it is important to use concepts that are applicable to all of them.Polity is a more general term that means any organization with a single authority that claims sovereign control over a territory or a group of people. Polities include bands, tribes and chiefdoms as well as states. All world-systems are politically composed of multiple interacting polities. Thus we can fruitfully compare the modern interstate system with earlier systems in which there were tribes or chiefdoms, but no states.[1]

In the modern world-system it is important to distinguish between nations and states. Nations are groups of people who share a common culture and a common language. Co-nationals identify with one another as members of a group with a shared history, similar food preferences and ideas of proper behavior.To a varying extent nations constitute a community of people who are willing to make sacrifices for one another.States are formal organizations such as bureaucracies that exercise and control legitimate violence within a specific territory.Some states in the modern world-system are nation-states in which a single nation has its own state. But others are multinational states in which more than one nation is controlled by the same state. Ethnic groups are sub-nations, usually minorities within states in which there is a larger national group.Ethnic groups and nations are sociologically similar in that they are both groups of people who identify with one another and share a common culture, but they often differ with regard to their relationship with states. Ethnic groups are minorities, whereas nations are majorities within a state. 

The modern world-system is also importantly structured as a core/periphery hierarchy in which some regions contain economically and militarily powerful states while other regions contain polities that are much less powerful and less developed.The countries that are called “advanced, ” in the sense that they have high levels of economic development, skilled labor forces, high levels of income and powerful, well-financed states, are the core powers of the modern system.The modern core includes the United States, and the countries of Europe, Japan, Australia and Canada. 

In the contemporary periphery we have relatively weak states that are not strongly supported by the populations within them, and have little power relative to other states in the system. The colonial empires of the European core states have dominated most of the modern periphery until recently.These colonial empires have undergone decolonization and the interstate system of formally sovereign states was extended to the periphery in a series of waves of decolonization that began in the last quarter of the eighteenth century with the American independence, follow in the early nineteenth century by the independence of the Spanish American colonies, and in the twentieth century by the decolonization of Asia and Africa. Peripheral regions are also economically less developed in the sense that the economy is composed of subsistence producers, as well as industries that have relatively low productivity and that employ unskilled labor.Agriculture in the periphery is typically performed using simple tools, whereas agriculture in the core is capital-intensive, employing machinery and non-human, non-animal forms of energy.Some industries in peripheral countries, such as oil extraction or mining, may be capital-intensive, but these sectors are often controlled by core capital.

In the past, peripheral countries have been primarily exporters of agricultural and mineral raw materials. But even when they have developed some industrial production, this has usually been less capital intensive and using less skilled labor than production processes in the core.The contemporary peripheral countries are most of the countries in Asia, Africa and Latin America – for example Bangla Desh, Senegal and Bolivia.

The core/periphery hierarchy in the modern world-system is a system of stratification in which socially structured inequalities are reproduced by the institutional features of the system (see Figure 2.2).The periphery is not “catching up” with the core. Rather both core and peripheral regions are developing, but most core states are staying well ahead of most peripheral states.There is also a stratum of countries that are in between the core and the periphery that we call the semiperiphery.The semiperiphery in the modern system includes countries that have intermediate levels of economic development or a balanced mix of developed and less developed regions. The semiperiphery includes large countries that have political/military power as a result of their large size, and smaller countries that are relatively more developed than those in the periphery. 

The modern semiperiphery includes Mexico, Brazil, Argentina, Venezuela, Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, Indonesia, China, India, South Africa, Russia, Israel, Ireland, Middle Eastern oil exporting countries, Hungary, Poland, and the Czech Republic. The hierarchies that exist between societies do not dissolve the class/caste hierarchies that exist within societies. The differences in absolute wealth between core and periphery, say between the United States and China, affects the comparative status and power of the classes within each society. To be upper middle-class in the core United States involves more wealth and power than being upper-middle class in semiperipheral China. So too, a member of the skilled working class in another core country, Germany, enjoys a higher standard of living than a skilled worker in Bolivia.












Figure 2.2: Core/Periphery Hierarchy

The exact boundaries between the core, semiperiphery and periphery are unimportant because the main point is that there is a continuum of economic and political/military power that constitutes the core-periphery hierarchy. It does not matter exactly where we draw lines across this continuum in order to categorize countries. Indeed we could as well make four or seven categories instead of three.The categories are only a convenient terminology for pointing to the fact of international inequality and for indicating that the middle of this hierarchy may be an important location for processes of social change.

There have been a few cases of upward and downward mobility in the core/periphery hierarchy, though most countries simply run hard to stay in the same relative positions that they have long had.A most spectacular case of upward mobility is the United States. Over the last 300 years the territory that became the U.S. has moved from outside the Europe-centered system (a separate continent containing several regional world-systems[2]), to the periphery, to the semiperiphery, to the core, to the position of hegemonic core state (see below), and now its hegemony is slowly declining. An example of downward mobility is the United Kingdom of Great Britain, the hegemon of the nineteenth century and now just another core society.

The global stratification system is a continuum of economic and political-military power that is reproduced by the normal operations of the system.In such a hierarchy there are countries that are difficult to categorize.For example, most oil-exporting countries have very high levels of GNP per capita, but their economies do not produce high technology products that are typical of core countries. They have wealth but not development. The point here is that the categories (core, periphery and semiperiphery) are just a convenient set of terms for pointing to different locations on a continuous and multidimensional hierarchy of power. It is not necessary to have each case fit neatly into a box. The boxes are only conceptual tools for analyzing the unequal distribution of power among countries. 

When we use the idea of core/periphery relations for comparing very different kinds of world-systems we need to broaden the concept a bit and to make an important distinction (see below).But the most important point is that we should not assume that all world-systems have core/periphery hierarchies just because the modern system does.It should be an empirical question in each case as to whether core/periphery relations exist.Not assuming that world-systems have core/periphery structures allows us to compare very different kinds of systems and to study how core/periphery hierarchies themselves emerged and evolved. 

In order to do this it is helpful to distinguish between core/periphery differentiation and core/periphery hierarchy.Core/periphery differentiation means that societies with different degrees of population density, polity size and internal hierarchy are interacting with one another. As soon as we find village dwellers interacting with nomadic neighbors we have core/periphery differentiation.Core/periphery hierarchy refers to the nature of the relationship between societies.This kind of hierarchy exists when some societies are exploiting or dominating other societies. Examples of intersocietal domination and exploitation would be the British colonization and deindustrialization of India, or the conquest and subjugation of Mexico by the Spaniards. Core/periphery hierarchy is not unique to the modern Europe-centered world-system of recent centuries. Both the Roman and the Aztec empires conquered and exploited peripheral peoples as well as adjacent core states.

Distinguishing between core/periphery differentiation and core/periphery hierarchy allows us to deal with situations in which larger and more powerful societies are interacting with smaller ones, but are not exploiting them. It also allows us to examine cases in which smaller, less dense societies may be exploiting or dominating larger societies. This latter situation definitely occurred in the long and consequential interactionbetween the nomadic horse pastoralists of Central Asia and the agrarian states and empires of China and Western Asia. The most famous case was that of the Mongol Empire of Chingis Khan, but confederations of Central Asian steppe nomads managed to extract tribute from agrarian states long before the rise of Mongols.

So the modern world-system is now a global economy with a global political system (the interstate system). It also includes all the cultural aspects and interaction networks of the human population of the Earth.Culturally the modern system is composed of:

·several civilizational traditions, (e.g. Islam, Christendom, Hinduism, etc.)

·nationally-defined cultural entities -- nations (and theseare composed of class and functional subcultures, e.g. lawyers, technocrats, bureaucrats, etc. ), and 

·the cultures of indigenous and minority ethnic groups within states.

The modern system is multicultural in the sense that important political and economic interaction networks connect people who have rather different languages, religions and other cultural aspects.Most earlier world-systems have also been multicultural. [3]

Interaction networks are regular and repeated interactions among individuals and groups.Interaction may involve trade, communication, threats, alliances, migration, marriage, gift giving or participation in information networks such as radio, television, telephone conversations, and email.Important interaction networks are those that affect peoples’ everyday lives, their access to food and necessary raw materials, their conceptions of who they are, and their security from or vulnerability to threats and violence.World-systems are fundamentally composed of interaction networks.

One of the important systemic features of the modern system is the rise and fall of hegemonic core powers – the so-called “hegemonic sequence.”A hegemon is a core state that has a significantly greater amount of economic power than any other state, and that takes on the political role of system leader.In the seventeenth century the Dutch Republic performed the role of hegemon in the Europe-centered system, while Great Britain was the hegemon of the nineteenth century, and the United States has been the hegemon in the twentieth century. Hegemons provide leadership and order for the interstate system and the world economy. But the normal operating processes of the modern system – uneven economic development and competition among states – make it difficult for hegemons to sustain their dominant positions, and so they tend to decline.Thus the structure of the core oscillates back and forth between hegemony and a situation in which several competing core states have a roughly similar amount of power and are contending for hegemony – i.e. hegemonic rivalry (see Figure 2.3).


 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

Figure 2.3: Hegemony and Hegemonic Rivalry

So the modern world-system is composed of states that are linked to one another by the world economy and other interaction networks.Earlier world-systems were also composed of polities, but the interaction networks that linked these polities were not intercontinental in scale until the expansion of Europe in the fifteenth century. Before that world-systems were smaller regional affairs. But these had been growing in size with the expansion of trade networks and long-distance military campaigns for millennia.

Spatial Boundaries of World-Systems

One big difference between the modern world-system and earlier systems is the spatial scale of different types of interaction networks.In the modern global system most of the important interaction networks are themselves global in scale. But in earlier smaller systems there was a significant difference in spatial scale between networks in which food and basic raw materials were exchanged and much larger networks of the exchange of prestige goods or luxuries.Food and basic raw materials we call “bulk goods” because they have a low value per unit of weight.Indeed it is uneconomical to carry food very far under premodern conditions of transportation.

Imagine that the only type of transportation available is people carrying goods on their backs (or heads). This is a situation that actually existed everywhere until the domestication of beasts of burden.Under these conditions a person can carry, say, 30 kilograms of food. Imagine that this carrier is eating the food as s/he goes. So after a few days walking all the food will be consumed. This is the economic limit of food transportation under these conditions of transportation.This does not mean that food will never be transported farther than this distance, but there would have to be an important reason for moving it beyond its economic range. 

A prestige good (e.g. a very valuable food such as spices, or jewels or bullion) hasa much larger spatial range because a small amount of such a good may be exchanged for a great deal of food.This is why prestige goods networks are normally much larger than bulk goods networks.A network does not usually end as long as there are people with whom one might trade.Indeed most early trade was what is called down-the-line trade in which goods are passed from group to group.For any particular group the effective extent of its of a trade network is that point beyond which nothing that happens will affect the group of origin. 

In order to bound interaction networks we need to pick a place from which to start – a so-called “place-centric approach.” If we go looking for actual breaks in interaction networks we will usually not find them, because almost all groups of people interact with their neighbors.But if we focus upon a single settlement, for example the precontact indigenous village of Onancock on the Eastern shore of the Chesapeake Bay (near the boundary between what are now the states of Virginia and Maryland), we can determine the spatial scale of the interaction network by finding out how far food moved to and from our focal village.Food came to Onancock from some maximum distance. A bit beyond that were groups that were trading food to groups that were directly sending food to Onancock. If we allow two indirect jumps we are probably far enough from Onancock so that no matter what happens (e.g. a food shortage or surplus), it would not have affected the supply of food in Onancock.This outer limit of Onancock’s indigenous bulk goods network probably included villages at the very southern and northern ends of the Chesapeake Bay. 

Onancock’s prestige goods network was much larger because prestige goods move farther distances.Indeed, copper that was in use by the indigenous peoples of the Chesapeake may have come from as far away as Lake Superior.In between the size of bulk goods networks (BGNs) and prestige goods networks (PGNs) are the interaction networks in which polities make war and ally with one another.These are called political-military networks (PMNs).[4]In the case of the Chesapeake world-system at the time of the arrival of the Europeans in the sixteenth century Onancock was part of a district chiefdom in a system of multi-village chiefdoms.Across the bay on the Western shore were at least two larger polities, the Powhatan and the Conoy paramount chiefdoms.These were core chiefdoms that were collecting tribute from a number of smaller district chiefdoms.Onancock was part of an interchiefdom system of allying and war-making polities. The boundaries of that network included some indirect links, just as the trade network boundaries did.Thus the political-military network (PMN) of which Onancock was the focal place extended to the Delaware Bay in the north and into what is now the state of North Carolina to the south. 

Information, like a prestige good, is light relative to its value. Information may travel far along trade routes and beyond the range of goods. Thus information networks (INs) are usually as large or even larger than Prestige Goods nets (PGNs).

A general picture of the spatial relationships between different kinds of interaction networks is presented in Figure 2.4.The actual spatial scale of important interaction needs to be determined for each world-system we study, but Figure 2.4 shows what is generally the case – that BGNs (bulk goods nets) are smaller than PMNs (political-military nets), and these are in turn smaller than PGNs (prestige goods nets) and INs (information nets).

 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

Figure 2.4 The Spatial Boundaries of World-Systems

Defined in the way that we have above, world-systems have grown from small to large over the past twelve millennia as societies and intersocietal systems have gotten larger, more complex and more hierarchical.This spatial growth of systems has involved the expansion of some and the incorporation of some into others. The processes of incorporation have occurred in several ways as systems distant from one another have linked their interaction networks.Because interaction nets are of different sizes, it is the largest ones that come into contact first. Thus information and prestige goods link distant groups long before they participate in the same political-military or bulk goods networks.The processes of expansion and incorporation brought different groups of people together and made the organization of larger and more hierarchical societies possible. It is in this sense that globalization has been going on for thousands of years.

Modes of Accumulation

In order to comprehend the qualitative changes that have occurred with the processes of social evolution we need to conceptualize different logics of development and the institutional modes by which socially created resources are produced and accumulated.All societies produce and distribute the goods that are necessary for everyday life. But the institutional means by which human labor is mobilized are very different in different kinds of societies.Small and egalitarian societies rely primarily on normative regulation organized as commonly shared understandings about the obligations that members of families have toward one another.When a hunter returns with his game there are definite rules and understandings about who should receive shares and how much.All hunters in foraging societies want to be thought of as generous, but they must also take care of some people (those for whom they are the most responsible) before they can give to others.

The normative order defines the roles and the obligations, and the norms and values are affirmed or modified by the continual symbolic and non-symbolic action of the people. This socially constructed consciousness is mainly about kinship, but it is also about the nature of the universe of which the human group is understood as a part.This kind of social economy is called a kin-based mode of production and accumulation. People work because they need food and they have obligations to provide food for others.Accumulation mainly involves the preservation and storage of food supplies for the season in which food will become scarce.Status is based on the reputation that one has as a good hunter, a good gatherer, a good family member, or a talented speaker.Group decisions are made by consensus, which means that the people keep talking until they have come to an understanding of what to do.The leaders have authority that is mainly based on their ability to convince others that they are right. These features are common (but not universal) among societies and world-systems in which the kin-based modes of accumulation are the main logic of development.

As societies become larger and more hierarchical, kinship itself becomes hierarchically defined. Clans and lineages become ranked so that members of some families are defined as senior or superior to members of other families. Classical cases of ranked societies were those of the Pacific Northwest, in which the totem pole represents a hierarchy of clans. This tendency toward hierarchical kinship resulted in the eventual emergence of class societies (complex chiefdoms) in which a noble class owned and controlled key resources and a class of commoners was separated from the control of important resources and had to rely on the nobles for access to these.Such a society existed in Hawaii before the arrival of the Europeans. 

The tributary modes of accumulation emerged when institutional coercion became a central form of regulation for inducing people to work and for the accumulation of social resources.Hierarchical kinship functions in this way when commoners must provide labor or products to chiefs in exchange for access to resources that chiefs control by means of both normative and coercive power.

Normative power does not work well by itself as a basis for the appropriation of labor or goods by one group from another. Those who are exploited have a great motive to redefine the situation. The nobles may have elaborated a vision of the universe in which they were understood to control natural forces or to mediate interactions with the deities and so commoners were supposed to be obligated to support these sacred duties by turning over their produce to the nobles or contributing labor to sacred projects. But the commoners will have an incentive to disbelieve unless they have only worse alternatives.Thus the institutions of coercive power are invented to sustain the extraction of surplus labor and goods from direct producers.The hierarchical religions and kinship systems of complex chiefdoms becamesupplemented in early states by specialized organizations of regional control -- groups of armed men under the command of the king and bureaucratic systems of taxation and tribute backed up by the law and by institutionalized force. The tributary modes of accumulation develop techniques of power that allowed resources to be extracted over great distances and from large populations. These are the institutional bases of the states and the empires. 

The third mode of accumulation is based on markets.Markets can be defined as any situation in which goods are bought and sold, but wewill use the term to denote what are called price-setting markets in which the competitive trading by large numbers of buyers and sellers is an important determinant of the price. This is a situation in which supply and demand operate on the price because buyers and sellers are bidding against one another.In practice there are very few instances in history or in modern reality of purely price-setting markets, because political and normative considerations quite often influence prices. But the price mechanism and resulting market pressures have become more important. These institutions were completely absent before the invention of commodities and money.

A commodity is a good that is produced for sale in a price-setting market in order to make a profit.A pencil is an example of a modern commodity. It is a fairly standardized product in which the conditions of production, the cost of raw materials, labor, energy and pencil-making machines are important forces acting upon the price of the pencil. Pencils are also produced for a rather competitive market, and so the socially-necessary costs given the current level of technology, plus a certain amount of profit, adds up to the cost.

The idea of the commodity is an important element of the definition of the capitalist mode of accumulation.Capitalism is the concentrated accumulation of profits by the owners of major means of the production of commodities in a context in which labor and the other main elements of production are commodified.Commodification means that things are treated as if they are commodities, even though they may have characteristics that make this somewhat difficult. So land can be commodified – treated as if it is a commodity – even though it is a limited good that has not originally been produced for profitable sale.There is only so much land on earth.We can divide it up into sections with straight boundaries and price it based on supply and demand. But it will never be a perfect commodity.So to with human labor time.

The commodification of land is an historical process that began when “real property” was first legally defined and sold. The conceptualization of places as abstract, measurable, substitutable and salable space is an institutional redefinition that took thousands of years to develop and to spread to all regions of the Earth. 

The capitalist modes of production also required the redefinition of wealth as money.The first storable and tradable valuables were probably prestige goods.These were used by local elites in trade with adjacent peoples, and eventually as symbols of superior status.Trade among simple societies is primarily organized as gift giving among elites in which allegiances are created and sustained.Originally prestige goods were used only in specific circumstances by certain elites. This “proto-money” was eventually redefined and institutionalized as the so-called “universal equivalent” that serves as a general measure of value for all sorts of goods and that can be used by almost anyone to buy almost anything. The institution of money has a long and complicated history, but suffice it to say here that it has been a prerequisite for the emergence of price-setting markets and capitalism as increasingly important forms of social regulation. Once markets and capital become the predominant form of accumulation we can speak of capitalist systems.

Patterns and Causes of Social Evolution

Before the story is told it will be helpful to have a map of the territory of world-systems evolution.This section describes a general causal model that explains the emergence of larger hierarchies and the development of productive technologies. It also points to a pattern that is noticeable only when we study world-systems rather than individual societies. The pattern is called semiperipheral development.This means that those innovations that transform the logic of development and allow world-systems to get larger and more hierarchical come mainly from semiperipheral societies.Some semiperipheral societies are unusually fertile locations for the invention and implementation of new institutional structures.And semiperipheral societies are not constrained to the same degree as older core societies from having invested huge resources in doing things in the old way. So they are freer to implement new institutions.

It will become evident in the chapters that follow that there are several different important kinds of semiperipheries, and that these not only transform systems but they also often take over and become new core societies.We have already mentioned semiperipheral marcher chiefdoms.The societies that conquered and unified a number of smaller chiefdoms into larger paramount chiefdoms were usually from semiperipheral locations.Peripheral peoples did not usually have the institutional and material resources that would allow them to make important inventions and to implement these or to take over older core regions.It was in the semiperiphery that core and peripheral social characteristics couldbe recombinedin new ways.Sometimes this meant that new techniques of power or political legitimacy were invented and implemented in semiperipheral societies.

Much better known than semiperipheral marcher chiefdoms is the phenomenon of semiperipheral marcher states.The largest empires have been assembled by conquerors who come from semiperipheral societies.The following semiperipheral marchers are well known:the Achaemenid Persians, the Macedonians led by Alexander The Great, the Romans, the Ottomans, the Manchus and the Aztecs. 

But some semiperipheries transform institutions, but do not take over.The semiperipheral capitalist city-states operated on the edges of the tributary empires where they bought and sold goods in widely separate locations, encouraging people to produce a surplus for trade.The Phoenician cities (e.g. Tyre, Carthage, etc.), as well as Malacca, Venice and Genoa, spread commodification by producing manufactured goods and trading them across great regions.In this way the semiperipheral capitalist city-states were agents of the development of markets and the expansion of trade networks, and so they helped to transform the world of the tributary empires without themselves becoming new core powers. 

In the modern world-system we have already mentioned the process of the rise and fall of hegemonic core states.All of the cases we mentioned – the Dutch, the British and the U.S. – were countries that had formerly been in semiperipheral positions relative to the regional core/periphery hierarchies within which they existed.And indeed the rise ofEurope within the larger Afroeurasian world-system was also a case of semiperipheral development, one in which a formerly peripheral and then semiperipheral region rose to become the new core of what had been a huge multi-core world-system.

The idea of semiperipheral development does not claim that all semiperipheral societies perform transformational roles, nor does it contend that every important innovation came from the semiperiphery. The point is rather that semiperipheries have been unusually prolific sites for the invention of those institutions that have expanded and transformed many small systems into the particular kind of global system that we have today. This observation would not be possible without the conceptual apparatus of the comparative world-systems perspective.

But what have been the proximate causes that led semiperipheral societies to invent new institutional solutions to problems?Some of the problems that needed to be solved were new unintended consequences of earlier inventions, but others were very old problems that kept emerging again and again as systems expanded – e.g. population pressure and ecological degradation.It is these basic problems that make it possible for us to specify a single underlying causal model of world-systems evolution.Figure 2.7 shows what is called the “ iteration model” that links demographic, ecological and interactional processes with the emergence of new production technologies, bigger polities and greater degrees of hierarchy.

 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

Figure 2.7 Basic Iteration Model of World-System Evolution

This is called an iteration model because it has an important positive feedback mechanism in which the original causes are themselves consequences of the things that they cause. Thus the process goes around and around, which is what has caused the world-systems to expand to the global level.Starting at the top we see population growth. The idea here is that all human societies contain a biological impetus to grow that is based on sexuality. This impetus is both controlled and encouraged by social institutions. Some societies try to regulated population growth by means ofe.g. infanticide, abortion and taboos on sexual relations during nursing.These institutional means of regulation are costly, and when greater amounts of food are available these types of regulation tend to be eased. Other kinds of societies encourage population growth by means of channeling sexual energy toward reproduction, pro-natalist ideologies and support for large families. All societies experience periodic “baby booms” when social circumstances are somewhat more propitious for reproduction, and thus, over the long run, the population tends to grow despite institutional mechanisms that try to control it.

Intensification is caused by population growth. This means that when the number of mouths to feed increases greater efforts are needed to produce food and other necessities of life and so people exploit the resources they have been exploiting more intensively.This usually leads, in turn, to ecological degradation because all human production processes use up the natural environment.More production leads to greater environmental degradation. This occurs because more resources are extracted, and because of the polluting consequences of production and consumption activities. Nomadic hunter-gatherers depleted the herds of big game and Polynesian horticulturalists deforested many a Pacific island. Environmental degradation is not a new phenomenon. Only its global scale is new.

As Jared Diamond (19xx) points out all continents around the world did not start with the same animal and plant resources. In West Asia both plants (barley and wheat) and animals (sheep, goats, cows, and oxen) were more easily domesticated than the plants and animals of Africa and the New World. Since domesticated plants and animals can more easily diffuse lattitudinally (East and West) than longitudinally (North and South) these inventions spread more quickly to Europe and East Asia than they did to Africa.

The consequences of the above processes are that the economics of production change for the worse.According to Joseph Tainter (19xx), after a certain point increased investment in complexity does not result in proportionate increasing returns. This occurs in the areas of agricultural production, information processing and communication, including education and maintenance of information channels. Sociopolitical control and specialization, such as military and the police, also develop diminishing returns. Tainter points out that marginal returns can occur in at least four instances: benefits constant, costs rising; benefits rising, costs rising faster; benefits falling, costs constant; benefits falling, costs rising.

When herds are depleted the hunters must go farther to find game.The combined sequence from population growth to intensification to environmental degradation leads to population pressure, the negative economic effects on production activities. The growing effort needed to produce enough food is a big incentive for people to migrate. And so humans populated the whole Earth.If the herds in this valley are depleted we may be able to find a new place where they are more abundant.

Migration eventually leads to circumscription. Circumscription is the condition that no new desirable locations are available for emigration.This can be because all the herds in all the adjacent valleys are depleted, or because all the alternative locations are deserts or high mountains, or because all adjacent desirable locations are already occupied by people who will resist our moving in with them.

The condition of social circumscription in which adjacent locations are already occupied is, under conditions of population pressure, likely to lead to a rise in the level of intergroup and intragroup conflict.This is because more people are competing for fewer resources.Warfare and other kinds of conflict are more prevalent under such conditions.All systems experience some warfare, but warfare becomes a focus of social endeavour that often has a life of its own.Boys are trained to be warriors and societies make decisions based on the presumption that they will be attacked or will be attacking other groups.Even in situations of seemingly endemic warfare the amount of conflict varies cyclically. Figure 2.7 shows an arrow with a negative sign going from conflict back to population pressure. This is because high levels of conflict reduce the size of the population as warriors are killed off and non-combatants die because their food supplies have been destroyed.Some systems get stuck in a vicious cycle of population pressure and warfare.

But situations such as this are also propitious for the emergence of new institutional structures.It is in these situations that semiperipheral development is likely to occur.People get tired of endemic conflict. One solution is the emergence of a new hierarchy or a larger polity that can regulate access to resources in a way that generates less conflict.The emergence of a new larger polity usually occurs as a result of successful conquest of a number of smaller polities by a semiperipheral marcher.The larger polity creates peace by means of an organized force that is greater than any force likely to be brought against it.The new polity reconstructs the institutions of control over territory and resources, often concentrating control and wealth for a new elite.And larger and more hierarchical polities often invest in new technologies of production that change the way in which resources are utilized. They produce more food and other necessaries by using new technologies or by intensifying the use of old technologies. New technologies can expand the number of people that can be supported in the territory.This makes population growth more likely, and so the iteration model is primed to go around again.

The iteration model has kept expanding the size of world-systems and developing new technologies and forms of regulation but, at least so far, it has not permanently solved the original problems of ecological degradation and population pressure. What has happened is the emergence of institutions such as states and markets that articulate changes in the economics of production more directly with changes in political organization and technology. This allows the institutional structures to readjust without having to go through short cycles at the messy bottom end of the model. 
 


 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

Figure 2.8: Temporary Institutional Shortcuts in the Iteration Model 

Another way to say this is that political and market institutions allow for some adjustments to occur without greatly increasing the level of systemic conflict. This said, the level of conflict has remained quite high, because the rate of expansion and technological change has increased.Even though institutional mechanisms of articulation have emerged, these have not permanently lowered the amount of systemic conflict because the rates of change in the other variables have increased.
Some theorists of social evolution claim that the model described above can explain some major transformations and expansions, but not others.This problem will be discussed at the point at which our story reaches the emergence of capitalism and the rise of Europe.

The basic ideas have now been described.We have a philosophical standpoint, a method, a theoretical approach (institutional materialism) and an orienting strategy (the comparative world-systems perspective).Let us now turn to the process by which an individual learns to become a social being by developing a social self, including the ability to reason abstractly

Now we have enough macrosociological tools from the comparative world-systems approach. Now let us turn to the social self, personality, identity and questions of the nature of the individual human being. With a carefully selected and thoughtfully packed bag of conceptual camping equipment we will be ready for an excursion into the realm of stateless systems and trekking with the nomads.

Notes


[1]We will discuss the differences between tribes, chiefdoms and states in the chapters that follow.
[2] See Chase-Dunn and Hall 19xx, “World-systems in North America.”
[3]But not all. The interchiefdom system of precontact Hawaiian islands was a complex world-system in which the ancestral Polynesian culture had regionally differentiated across the islands.
[4]The PMN of the contemporary global system is the international system of states studied by students of international relations.