“Globalization, the Structure of the World Economy and Economic
Development”*
Matthew C. Mahutga
Department of Sociology
1226 Watkins Hall
Riverside, CA. 92521, USA.
Phone: (951)
827-5852
Fax: (951) 827-3330
David A. Smith
Department of Sociology
3151 Social Science Plaza A
This is IROWS Working Paper #52 and is available at https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows52/irows52.htm
Institute for Research on World-Systems (IROWS)
College Building South
University of California-Riverside
*We would like to thank Jason Beckfield, Susan Brown, Rob
Clark, Katie Faust, Matt Huffman and the participants of the UC Irvine network
research groups for helpful comments on earlier drafts. Preliminary versions were presented at the
Sunbelt Social Network Conference; the annual PEWS section conference, and an
annual meeting of the American Sociological Association. Send all comments, questions and
correspondence to Matthew C. Mahutga, Department of Sociology,
“Globalization, the Structure of the World Economy and Economic Development”
How does the structure of the world economy determine the gains from participation therein? Does globalization alter that relationship? In order to answer these questions, we conduct a state of the art network analysis of international trade to map the structure of the international division of labor (IDL). We regress cross-national variation in economic growth on positional variation and mobility of countries within the IDL from 1965 to 2000. Our findings indicate that structure plays an extremely important role in the development trajectory of nations. Specifically, we find that the highest rates of economic growth occurred to countries in the middle of the IDL over the course of globalization. Second, we find that upper tier positions in the IDL are converging vis-à-vis each other, but diverging vis-à-vis the lower tier. Thus, finally, we show that the mechanism underlying the rapid economic growth in intermediate positions was their uniquely high rates of upward mobility, in turn a function of their middling position. Taken together, these findings suggest that a country’s long-term economic development is conditioned to a large extent by its position in the IDL. We close by calling for new directions in the debate on the impact of globalization on economic growth in the world-economy.
Keywords: Globalization, Economic Development, International Division of Labor, Inequality, Network Analysis.
One of
sociology’s most significant historical and contemporary contributions to the
social sciences lies in the basic insight that social structure—the concrete
relations between social actors—plays a causal role in shaping the life
experiences of actors therein (Durkheim 1997; Granovetter 1973; 1985; Marx
1977; Weber 1978). In the sociological
study of the wealth and poverty of nations, there has been no bigger structural
intuition than that of world-system theory.
Paraphrasing a major theme from this approach, a “country's
world-system position, in a macro-structural sense, is considered the key
determinant of the society's capacity for sustained economic growth and
development” (Crowly, Rauch, Seagrove and Smith 1998:32). The key relational
insight is that the world-system is composed of a “single ongoing division of
labor…based on differential appropriation of the surplus produced [such that]
positions are hierarchically ordered, not just differentiated” (Evans 1979b:
15-16). For nearly two decades after its
emergence in the mid-1970s the world-systems perspective dominated the
sociological study of economic development.
In spite
of previous work that found support for the notion that world-system position
is positively associated with economic growth (Nemeth and Smith 1985; Snyder
and Kick 1979; Kick et. al. 2000; Kick and
Davis 2001), their is a high degree of skepticism about the saliency of social
structure as a determinant of development over the course of
globalization. One of the more important
reasons for this skepticism may be that the purported key empiric one would
expect given the existence of a world economic structure that causes
differential appropriation—rising global income inequality—doesn’t square with
a significant portion of the empirical evidence (eg. Firebaugh 2003; cf.
Milanovic 2005).
ENHANCING WELFARE OR ENTRENCHING HEIRARCHY? THE INTERNATIONAL DIVISION OF LABOR, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND UPWARD MOBILITY
The story of winners and losers in the IDL remains an important and hotly debated topic in the social sciences. In recent years the debate is often cast in terms of macro-level trends in global income inequality. Readers of social science literature on trends in “total world inequality” are confronted with two distinct and contrasting views: The first is that inequality increased over recent years (Dowrick and Akmal 2005; Kickanov and Ward 2001; Bourguignon and Morrison 1999; 2002; Chotikapanich, Valenzuela and Rao 1997; Jones 1997; Korzeniewicz and Moran 1997; Pritchett 1997). A second body of literature reaches a very different conclusion, claiming that global inequality leveled off by the end of the 1990s, and is now beginning to decrease, in spite of rising within country inequality (Bhatta 2002; Firebaugh 2003; Firebaugh and Goesling 2004; Goesling 2001; Melchior and Telle 2001; Sala-I-Martin 2002; Schultz 1998).
One of the reasons for these
contradictory findings is the inherent difficulty in obtaining valid estimates of individual
income cross-nationally, coupled with the methodological challenge of
approximating the person-to-person income distribution with state level
aggregate data. Thus, Milonovic (2006)
asserts that previous attempts at measuring “total world inequality” should be
“considered ‘tatonnements,’ groping for the global distribution”
(6). In addition to the methodological
challenge of measuring global income inequality over time, its relevance to the
question of how the world-economic structure impacts development outcomes is
also in question because of the fact that one country—China—accounts for nearly
all of the decreased inequality observed in studies that find a leveling /
falling trend.[1] In other words, the sensitivity of measures
of contemporary global inequality to China’s rapid economic growth make
these indices less relevant to
understanding how the world-economy impacts development outcomes for less
developed countries in general because China’s unique characteristics
set it apart from the rest (Dowrick 2004).
Moreover, there has been no discussion to our knowledge of the role that
While the debate about world inequality may be of interest in and of itself, an important underlying issue is an old, very basic, one in comparative sociology and political economy: How does the structure of the world-economy impact economic development and the wealth / poverty of nations? The key point of contention revolves around two views of the role that the international division of labor plays in the development of individual countries. As Peter Evans (1995) argues, “the international division of labor can be seen as the basis of enhanced welfare or as a hierarchy” (7).
The “enhanced welfare” view claims that any one particular role in the IDL is not necessarily better than another, but rather that “compatibility with [a country’s] resource and factor endowments defines the activity most rewarding for each country” (Evans 1995: 7; also see the classic treatments of Ricardo [1817] 2004; Smith [1776] 2003). This view informs classical economic growth models that predict “absolute convergence” across countries, as the returns to capital tend to diminish over time in capital-intensive wealthy economies. Absolute convergence implies an inverse relationship between initial levels of GDP per capita—the average ratio of capital to labor—and subseqent economic growth across countries (Barro and Sala-I-Martin 1995; Solow 1956; Swan 1956).
Empirically, absolute convergence does not mesh well with observed growth trends across countries, which betray no negative bivariate correlation between initial levels of income and economic growth. Thus economic growth theory focuses instead on the idea of “conditional convergence” (Barro and Sala-I-Martin 1995; Islam 2003). In the context of cross-sectional regression, conditional convergence materializes when initial levels of GDP per capita have a negative relationship to subsequent growth only after controlling for variables that would be highly correlated with a variable that captures a country’s position in the IDL, such as measures of physical and human capital, levels of technology, certain types of institutions and so on (Barro and Sala-I-Martin 1995). Holding these crucial variables constant, studies find that poorer countries grow faster than wealthier ones (Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1995; Islam 2003).
The “enhanced welfare” position contrasts sharply with global political economy arguments that development outcomes vary by a country’s position in the IDL (Chase-Dunn 1998; Galtung 1971). Indeed, the world-system perspective argues that the IDL conforms to hierarchically stratified zones with divergent types of production occurring across the various zones: “Core production is relatively capital intensive and employs skilled, high wage labor; peripheral production is labor intensive and employs cheap, often politically coerced labor” (Chase-Dunn 1998: 77). In turn, they argue that core positions “generate a ‘multidimensional conspiracy’ in favor of development,” while peripheral ones do not (Evans 1995: 7). Thus, while the conditional convergence hypothesis attempts to “hold constant” certain factors that vary between countries such as position in the IDL, others argue that cross-country differences in these factors cause divergent growth patterns between countries.
With respect to empirical expectations regarding the association between position in the IDL and economic growth, the “enhanced welfare” view presents a simple null hypothesis: if the structure of the international division of labor is simply “differentiated” rather than hierarchically organized, we would expect that cross-national variation in structural location should not be a significant predictor of economic growth. On the other hand, the world-systems perspective offers two distinct hypotheses corresponding to different phases in the cycles of world-economic expansion and contraction. The first is a linear hypothesis—the core grows faster than the semiperiphery and the periphery, and the semiperiphery grows faster than the periphery.
The world-systems perspective is also consistent with a non-linear hypothesis—the semiperiphery grows faster than both the core and the periphery—corresponding to a particular phase in long term Kondratieff cycles of world-economic expansion and contraction (Wallerstein 1976). During world-economic upswings—Kondratieff A phases—core countries reap the benefits of an expansionary economy and the association between position in the IDL and economic growth is linear. However, Wallerstein suggests that the world-economy entered a down turn—and Kondratieff B phase—circa 1967, during which there was a “shift in relative profit advantage to the semi-peripheral nations” (Wallerstein 1976: 464; 1998). According to Wallerstein’s depiction of Kondratieff B phases, select countries in the semiperiphery become the beneficiaries of the relocation of global industries to non-core countries. In other words, the B phase represents the greatest possibility for growth owing to the greater openness of the system to the flow of mature technologies out from the core.
In sum, there are three competing claims made the relationship between the IDL and development. The first contrasts the “enhanced welfare” view with the “hierarchy view,” where the former argues that all roles in the IDL are conducive to growth and the latter argues that only “core-like” positions are. These claims can be summarized with the following hypotheses:
Hypothesis 0: The structure of the IDL has no effect on economic growth, such that growth will be the same across positions of the IDL. Hypothesis 1: The structure of the IDL has a positive effect on economic growth, such that core growth exceeds that in the semiperiphery, and semi-peripheral growth exceeds that of the periphery. Finally, the non-linear claims can be summarized with Hypothesis 2: The structure of the IDL benefits countries in the middle during times of economic downturn and industrial migration, such that semi-peripheral growth exceeds that of both the core and the periphery.
Mobility in the IDL and
Economic Growth
While Wallerstein’s explication of Kondratieff cycles leads to an expectation of rapid growth in the semiperiphery, the mechanisms behind this dynamism are less understood. The mechanism we propose stems from the logical extension of the hierarchical view of the IDL: differential upward mobility in the international division of labor may explain why semi-peripheral countries gain in ways that peripheral ones do not. In developing this argument, we draw on a large and growing literature on global commodity chains, which focuses on the way in which firms from the lower tier of the IDL link up with those at upper tiers of the IDL in order to “upgrade” their role in the chain at the firm level, and the IDL at the level of the national economy (Bair 2005; Gereffi and Korzeniewicz 1994; Gereffi et al. 2001; 2005; Gereffi and Memedovic 2003; Memedovic 2004). Moreover, we develop our argument by progressing dialogically through two points of contention regarding the relationship between upward mobility and development.
The first point of contention involves whether or not
upward mobility generates positive development outcomes at all. Some are willing to acknowledge that the
“growth miracles” in countries such as
The second point of contention involves whether or not upward mobility is viable, stemming from disagreements, both within the world-systems community and outside it, over “the degree of mobility within the system available to individual states” (Chase-Dunn and Grimes 1995: 397). Some argue that “it is highly unlikely that countries with little to no advanced industry can move up because they lack the necessary levels of capital, infrastructure, workforces skills and technical expertise to do so” (Mahutga 2006: 1865). There is a sense that “(t)he poverty, dependence, and lopsided development of peripheral societies, perpetuated a problem, which made it more difficult for them to break out of this pattern” (Chirot 1986:104). Classic dependency theory, exemplified by Andre Gunder-Frank (1969), presents an extremely “stagnationist” version of this position. On the other hand, even within the Latin American dependista tradition, there is an interest in discovering how “dependency reversal” can take place leading to some form of more “autonomous” growth in relation to “external” global structures, promoting genuine economic development (Gereffi 1983: Chapter 1; Evans 1979a and b). The idea of “dependent development” (see, especially Evans 1979a) explicitly theorized the possibility of upward mobility in the world-system, particularly among the newly industrializing countries (Caporaso 1981, Deyo 1987).
Empirically, there are examples of upwardly mobile countries that experience real development (e.g. Amsden 2001; Evans 1979; Gereffi and Wyaman 1990), those that seem to experience upward mobility without subsequent economic development (e.g. Schrank 2004), and still other cases that experience neither mobility nor development (e.g. Frank 1969). As a resolution to these points of contention, we suggest that some unique characteristics of countries in the middle of the IDL may give us some theoretical leverage in understanding these disagreements. First, most acknowledge that upward mobility—or industrial upgrading—stems, at least to a large degree, from the outsourcing decisions of, and / or technological diffusion from, firms in core countries (Bair 2005; Dicken 2003; Gereffi 1994; Gereffi and Memedovic 2003; Gereffi and Korzeniewicz 1994; Parente and Prescott 2000). While, for the sake of simplicity, many economists assume that countries have equal access to the world stock of “usable knowledge,” or advanced production technologies developed exogenously, as well as the minimum infrastructural basis to implement advanced production technologies they do access (Parente and Prescott 2000), these assumptions seem unlikely from a sociological point of view.
For example, semi-peripheral countries contain either “a relatively equal mix of core and peripheral types of production,” or “a predominance of activities which are at intermediate levels with regard to the current world-system distribution of capital intensive/labor intensive production (Chase-Dunn 1998: 77, 212). Regardless of whether middle countries “average out” to intermediate skill levels and production capacity, or produce at an intermediate level economy wide, they should conceivably possess advantages over both the core and periphery in two respects.
First, they should possess considerably lower production costs vis-à-vis the core because of their intermediate skill level. Second, they should also possess considerably higher level of access to and ability to implement exogenous technology than the periphery, for two reasons. On one hand, countries that gain experience and competence with one firm or industry often become more attractive to others, such that early experience leads to greater future access (Cohen et al. 2009). Moreover, countries with a greater degree of manufacturing experience should have higher “absorptive capacity” in that firms that relocate to poorer countries must balance the expected gains from lower production costs against the amount of time required for the new location to produce comparable commodities to the home country, and more experience translates into a steeper learning curve (Thun 2008; Wood 1994: Chapter 9).
In short, countries at intermediate positions of the IDL are much more likely to have the minimum level of experience and capability necessary to implement exogenously produced production technologies, while at the same time possessing wage levels low enough to access transnational corporate outsourcing behavior (Kaplinsky 2005; 2000). Thus, the question of mobility’s impact on development may be resolved by arguing that mobility is a viable developmental path, but that middle countries occupy structural positions that encourage upward mobility more than others.
These debates over the effect of IDL mobility on economic growth can be summarized with our final set of hypotheses. First, the debate over whether or not mobility has an effect on economic growth can be tested with our third hypothesis—Hypothesis 3: Mobility in the IDL is positively associated with economic growth. Second, our resolution to the quandary about the apparent cross-country variation in the association between mobility and economic growth can be tested with Hypothesis 4: Economic growth in the semiperiphery and periphery will be equal, holding mobility constant. We turn now to a discussion of our data and methodological strategy.
NETWORK METHODS AND DATA
Roles and Positions in the IDL
Given our concern with the effect of a country’s position in the international division of labor on its development trajectory, we begin by mapping that structure and identifying the position of individual countries within it. Our research strategy builds upon a solid foundation of previous research that attempted to characterize the structure of the world economy by analyzing patterns of cross-national relationships (Breiger 1981; Mahutga 2006; Nemeth and Smith 1985; Smith and White 1992; Snyder and Kick 1979; Van Rossem 1996). Much of this work was motivated by a key relational insight in the literature, namely that uncovering the structure of the world-economy involves a “…shift from a concern with the attributive characteristics of states to a concern with the relational characteristics of states” (Wallerstein 1989: xi). In short, because the international division of labor is a relational concept—firms and states play distinct roles in the IDL that achieve definition only in relation to other firms and states—relationships are the most theoretically appropriate type of data with which to model the IDL.
We use network analytic techniques to identify both the global structure of the international division of labor and locate the position of individual countries within that structure. Our approach follows the classic literature on the identification of roles and positions in network analysis (Wasserman and Faust 1999: 347-393; 461-502), implemented in a wide variety of empirical contexts (Anheier and Gerhards 1991; Boorman and White 1976; Mullins et al. 1977 White et al. 1976), and in studies of the structure of the world economy in particular (Alderson and Beckfield 2004; Breiger 1981; Mahutga 2006; Nemeth and Smith 1985; Smith and White 1992; Snyder and Kick 1979; Van Rossem 1996).
At a conceptual level, the
identification of roles and positions begins with the supposition that actors
in similar structural positions should have relatively isomorphic patterns of
relations to others. Thus, the goal is
to identify the latent structure of a set of relationships by determining the
extent to which each dyad has interchangeable patterns of relationships and
therefore structural positions. The
method starts with a relation or set of relations and then (1) estimates the
degree of similarity between each actor’s relations to / from all others with
an equivalence criterion, (2) uses these estimates as the basis for assigning
actors to relatively equivalent structural positions (either categorically,
continuously, or both), and sometimes (3) determines the role played by each of
the equivalent groups by analyzing the relations within and between equivalent
groupings (or “blocks” in the block model literature). For the purposes of this paper, our network
analysis is largely confined to the first and second steps above, but auxiliary
analyses confirming unique core, semi-peripheral and peripheral role sets were entirely consistent with current
understandings of the globalization of different types of industries and
previous research (Gereffi 1999; Mahutga 2006; see note 3).
The first step in our analysis follows previous research by obtaining
the degree of regular equivalence between each country in our sample across
five different trade relationships (see below) at each time point. Regular equivalence is appropriate over other
types of equivalencies because it is a more general measure of role similarity
(Faust 1988; White 1984). Regular
equivalence locates actors who relate to other actors in a network in the same
way. Specifically, “the notion of
regular equivalence formalizes the observation that actors who occupy the same
social position relate in the same ways with other actors who are themselves in
the same positions” (Wasserman and Faust 1999: 473). More formally, “two
points in a network are regularly equivalent if and only if for each tie one
has with another point, the self-equivalent point has an identical tie with an
other-equivalent point” (White and Reitz 1985: 12). In the present analysis, the regular
equivalence (Mt+1 ij) between countries i and j at iteration t +
1 is:
(1)
where
the denominator is the maximum possible value of the matches between the
profiles of ik and jm that would occur if all of the ties between
i and its alters (k) were perfectly matched to the ties between j
and its alters (m), and all of k and m were regularly
equivalent on each relation (R).
For each relation analyzed, the numerator determines the best matching
of the ties between j and m for i’s ties to k
weighted by the regular equivalence of k and m from the previous
iteration (Wasserman and Faust 1999), while the denominator is the maximum
possible value of the numerator for each pair of countries. The algorithm above is an iterative process
in which the regular equivalence of each dyad’s neighborhood changes and
equivalencies are summed across all relations at each iteration. We specify three iterations, with the third
serving as the measure of regular equivalence for each pair of countries, as
suggested in the literature (Faust 1988).
In short, the above algorithm determines the best possible
matching of ties between i and j, weighted by the equivalence of
their alters, and divides that value by the maximum possible value of the
numerator across all five relations. It
is highly unlikely that any two nations would be exactly equivalent, so our
multi-relational regular equivalence analysis produces a single equivalence
matrix consisting of an equivalence measure for each pair of countries between
maximally dissimilar (0) and regularly equivalent (1) in each period. Each trade matrix was transformed with the
base 10 logarithm to reduce skew prior their joint submission to the REGE
algorithm in UCINET.
Having identified the level of regular equivalence between each country, our second step combines two complementary techniques—correspondence analysis and hierarchical clustering—to locate the position of countries in a low dimensional continuous “coreness space,” and to identify cut points along that continuum within which groups of countries occupy relatively equivalent IDL positions. The “complete link” hierarchical clustering routine generates groups of countries that are approximately regularly equivalent by assigning actors to groups that maximize the within group similarity in regular equivalence (Borgatti 1994; Johnson 1967; Wasserman and Faust 1999). However, the hierarchical clustering routine produces many possible sets of equivalent groupings that span the continuum from a trivial set in which each actor occupies its own position to another trivial set in which all actors occupy the same position. In principle, an analyst could start out with some α criterion whereby actors i and j would be placed in the same group if REij > α. However, there is no a priori theory that favors one level of α over another, large real world data sets are rarely broken down into discrete homogenous groups at any single α and the authoritative guide states simply that the “trick is to find the most useful and interpretable partition of actors into equivalence classes” (Wasserman and Faust 1999: 383). Thus, we use the hierarchical clustering results in conjunction with correspondence analysis that we discuss below.
Correspondence analysis is one of a family of scaling techniques, including principal components analysis, factor analysis, and others, that draw upon the computational foundation of the singular value decompositions (SVD). At a conceptual level, correspondence analysis allows us to represent the matrix of regular equivalencies in a low-dimensional Euclidian space by assigning coordinates to actors that place them close to those with whom they are similar and far from those with whom they are dissimilar (Greenacre 1984; Weller and Romney 1990). Moreover, correspondence analysis is also useful for validating inter-group boundaries obtained from clustering techniques by superimposing the clustering solution onto the continuous spatial representation, as will be shown below.
Computationally, correspondence analysis decomposes the information contained in a data matrix into three matrices: an N-1 dimensional U matrix summarizing the information in the rows, an N-1 dimensional V matrix summarizing the information in the columns, and an N-1 diagonal d matrix of singular values that summarizes the amount of variance explained in each dimension of U and V, where larger singular values correspond to higher explained variance. Differences between correspondence analysis and, say, principal components analysis stem only from different data pre-processing techniques performed prior to SVD. One can evaluate the adequacy of representation, or fit, for single or multiple dimensions with the following equation, analogous to R2:
PRE = , (2)
where M is
singular value 1, 2, 3, …M. A
high PRE indicates an adequate fit while a low PRE indicates a poor fit.
In sum, correspondence assigns coordinates to each actor such that similar actors are spatially proximate and dissimilar actors are spatially distant. Interpreting the results from correspondence analysis depends on the amount of variation explained by each dimension and the observed spatial pattern of objects in the Euclidian space. Thus, one can have a relatively simple structure (few significant dimensions) or a complex one (many significant dimensions). Because our correspondence analysis is standard, we refer the interested reader to orthodox texts for the technical aspects of the analysis (Greenacre 1984; Weller and Romney 1990).
A major benefit to the dual use of
hierarchical clustering and correspondence analysis is that the latter produces
an objective scaling—any two analysts would produce the same result—that
mitigates some of the subjectivity of choosing among the many possible
clustering partitions (also see note 7).
The continuous scaling also allows us to develop a more refined measure
of mobility (see below) compared to previous work because it captures variation
both within and between categorical positions.
All network analyses
were carried out with UCINET, version 6 (Borgatti, Everett and Freeman 2002).
As discussed above, the measurement
of roles and positions is based on the supposition that similarly positioned
actors are defined by the similarity in their relationships to others in the
network. In the case of country level
positions in the structure of the international division of labor, this
supposition must account for the vast organizational variation across
industries. For example, while “core”
nodes in labor intensive industries—or buyer-driven commodity chains—are
identifiable by their tendency toward importing rather than domestic
production, and to import from a geographically diffuse set of low-wage countries,
“core” nodes in capital and technology intensive industries—or producer-driven
commodity chains—are identifiable by their tendency to engage in scale
intensive production with the goal of capturing a large share of the world
market (Gereffi 1994). In short,
patterns of trade—imports and exports in this case—do not mean the same thing
across different types of commodities because of differences in the way their
production is organized, such that similarly positioned countries should have
relatively equivalent patterns of trade relationships across different types
of industries.
The data underlying our measure of role / position in the IDL are trade in commodity groups from UN COMTRADE, classified under the Standard International Trade Classification (SITC, Rev. 1) and collected at three time points: 1965, 1980 and 2000 (United Nations, 1963). Rev. 1 of the SITC consists of 55 categories at the two-digit level. However, we collect data on 15 two-digit U.N. categories that represent the five broader relationships discovered by Smith and Nemeth (1988) displayed in Table 1[2]. Using factor analysis, Smith and Nemeth (1988) found that the 55 two-digit UN commodity categories cluster into 5 more-or-less equivalent types of relationships based on the pattern of their exchange between countries. In other words, the 5 relational categories in Table 1 capture the full spectrum of UN categories from which to choose, such that we can account for the UN’s 55 two-digit commodity categories with the 5 broad relationships in Table 1 at the same time that we retain all the meaningful organizational variation that exists between commodity categories.[3] In order to simplify our analyses, we take the sum of the three matrices within each category in Table 1 (, where r indexes the matrices in relation R) to produce five matrices representing each of the five types of relationships uncovered by Smith and Nemeth (1988) in 1965, 1980 and 2000.
[Table 1: UN Commodity Categories Classified by Level / Type
of Processing about here].
Our sample of countries is representative of all world-regions, and which contains a large number of less developed countries. The 94 countries in our sample collectively account for between 92 and 98 percent of world GDP over time, between 96 and 99 percent of world trade over time, and roughly 80 percent of world population over time (see Table A1 in the appendix for a list of included countries).[4]
Having delineated the global structure of the IDL and located the position of individual countries within that structure, we calculate the average rates of economic growth and mobility for each of our relatively equivalent groups, which serve as the first step in testing the hypotheses we develop above. Subsequently, we test those hypotheses that remain plausible after an examination of the aggregate trends in growth and mobility with cross-national growth regressions. Below we discuss the data and methods used for hypothesis testing.
Data
Dependent Variable
Economic growth
The
dependent variable in the regressions that follow is the standard annualized
growth rate of per capita gross domestic product (GDP) for each country (Barro
and Sala-i-Martin 1995). The annualized
growth rate for country during period t1-t0 is defined in
Table A3.
Control Variables
In order to provide robustness for our hypothesis tests, we select a series of control variables that are shown to be correlated with growth, and which could serve as alternative explanations for any observed growth differences across countries.
Initial GDP per capita
Controlling for initial levels of GDP per capita has become fairly standard practice in neo-classical models of economic growth (eg. Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1995). It accounts for any tendency towards diminishing returns to capital, and also serves as the variable of interest in tests for conditional convergence. Moreover, controlling for it here allows us to differentiate between causal pathways that run from a country’s position in the IDL and those that run from a country’s aggregate capital intensity.
Human Capital
Secondary education
enrollment rates are seen as key determinants of growth insofar as they proxy
for the cross-national variation in the stock of human capital (Barro and
Sala-i-Martin 1995).
Trade Openness
Trade openness plays a
dual role in this analysis. On one hand,
trade openness captures either the effect of government induced open trade
policy (IMF 1997), the potential for trade openness to induce technology and
knowledge transfer (Krueger 1998), or the classic view of the efficiency
promoting effects of producing / trading with respect to a country’s
comparative advantage (Ricardo 1817). On
the other hand, because our structural positions derive from trade, including
trade openness also controls for the potential conflation bias between it and a
country’s structural position.
Population Growth
It is also important to
assess whether or not any slow economic growth we observe in non-core countries
is an artifact of rapidly growing population.
Because population is the denominator of GDP per capita, a major
explanation given for the universal finding of unweighted economic divergence
between countries is the higher than average rate of population growth in poor
countries: a high ratio of population growth to labor force growth slows down
per capita growth by expanding the non-working age portion of the denominator
faster than the working age portion can produce (Sheehey 1996). Thus, in order to make sure these findings
are not an artifact of population growth, we also control for it.[5]
Regional / Institutional
Variation
In
addition to the standard growth covariates discussed above, we also integrate
dummy variables to account for growth variation attributable to institutional
and other unmeasurables that vary by region.
We create indicators for Africa (excluding North Africa), Central and
Eastern Europe, Latin America (comprised of Mexico, Central America, the
Caribbean and South America), Middle East (including North African countries),
the “West” (Western Europe and Maddison’s (2001) “Western Offshoots”), and Asia
(including East, South and Southeast Asia).
Table A1 shows which countries are in which regions. Our decision to model these effects as fixed
across institutional / regional groupings stems from several related
points. While some empirical work does
find that certain institutional configurations are an important growth
determinant among developed countries (e.g. Hicks and Kenworthy 1998), there is
also increasing reason to believe that there exists a strong and growing
tendency toward high institutional convergence within regions (Beckfield 2005;
Kim and Shin 2002), creating greater variation between than within them.
Second, while there are many proposed institutional
covariates with growth—including political, economic and social
institutions—the level of understanding with respect to the causal narratives
varies greatly across institutional types, the robustness of many institutional
covariates is not very high (e.g. Brady et al. 2005) and there is little
agreement in terms of measurement strategies (e.g. Bollen 1990; Temple 1999),
which is only compounded when including poorer countries in the analysis. Thus, rather than trying to specify the
plethora of potential institutional sources of variation, we follow Temple
(1999) and simply control for time invariant ones accounted for by the
approximate regional / institutional groupings discussed above, which will also
capture other potential sources of time-invariant variation across
institutional regions.
Finally, our decision to group western countries into a
single category rather than separate regional groupings (North America, Western
Europe and
Correlations
and descriptive statistics appear in Table A2, data sources and further
description appear in Table A3.
Regression Methods
In order to test the hypotheses we develop in sections two
and three, we estimate regression models where economic growth is regressed on
indicators for core and periphery (semiperiphery is the excluded category), IDL
mobility, and a series of control variables.
In order to enlarge the statistical power of our models, we pool the
observations across two growth periods (1965-1980 and 1980-2000). Pooling these data also allow us to account
for two types of omitted variable bias.
One type of omitted variable that could bias these analyses would vary
across units but not over time (unit effect).
The most conservative technique for dealing with unit effects is the
fixed effects model (FEM), which is equivalent to OLS but including a series of
dummy variables for N-1 units. Yet,
research shows that, in the context of cross-national economic growth
equations, “the results from fixed effects estimation are often found to be
disappointing” (Temple 1999: 132).
For example, while the FEM approach eliminates between country variation in the estimation of coefficients, most growth analysts are primarily interested in understanding how the between case variation in a given variable affects the between case variation in growth. This is an important theoretical caveat that is reflected in the structure of our data: unreported analyses show that the ratio of between to within variance for our structural covariates is overwhelming significant, with more than ninety percent of the variance residing between cases. Moreover, a byproduct of removing between case variation is that the consistency of the FEM approach is low in “short” panels, i.e. in panels where the ratio of cross-sectional observations to time-series observations is low (Halaby 2004; Wooldridge 2002). Further, FEM models are unable to capture the effect of time invariant—or nearly invariant—covariates such as core, periphery and semiperiphery because they are perfectly, or near perfectly, collinear with the fixed effects, another counterpart to the elimination of between case variation. Still, we do follow Temple (1999) and include the regional level fixed effects described above, which are likely to capture much of the meaningful variation attributable to unit effects that tend to vary more between than within regions, while maintaining a greater degree of identifying variation on each side of the equation (Koop et. al. 1995; Temple 1999: 132).[6]
Another type of omitted variable is one
that varies over time but not over units (period effects). We include a period specific fixed effect for
the first period (1965-1980) in order to control for this source of bias. Finally, pooled data of the type analyzed
here are also often plagued with both heteroskedasticity and spatial contemporaneous
autocorrelation. Thus, standard errors
are obtained using panel corrected standard errors (PCSE) (Beck and Katz 1995).
In our final models utilizing lagged mobility, standard errors are
obtained with a heteroskedasticity consistent covariance matrix. Because these data may violate some standard
assumptions of regression analysis such as independent observations and random
sampling, we also estimated all models using bootstrap standard errors
(Snijders and Borgatti 1999), which were substantively identical. All regressions were carried out with Stata
9.2.
[Figures 1 – 3 about here]
Figures 1 – 3 graph the first and second dimensions from our correspondence analysis of regular equivalencies, with the first six groups from our hierarchical clustering results superimposed. Previous research shows that a simple core/periphery structure will manifest high variation explained by the first dimension, with subsequent dimensions decreasing monotonically in terms of explained variance (Borgatti and Everett 1999; Boyd et. al. 2006b; Mahutga 2006; Smith and White 1992). As Table 2 shows, the first non-trivial dimension—that displayed on the X-axis of Figures 1-3—explains nearly all the variance at each time point, suggesting that the role and position analysis is identifying a latent core / periphery structure. Moreover, the ellipses in Figures 1 – 3 represent two-dimensional 95 percent confidence intervals centered on the mean location of each group. The fact that they do not overlap nor contain any countries from other groups demonstrates that the hierarchical clustering results are locating more or less equivalent groups along the continuous first—“coreness”—dimension of the correspondence analysis.[7]
[Table 2: Explained variance of correspondence analysis by dimension and year about here]
The first dimension from our correspondence analysis—the “coreness” of each actor—moves from high to low as you move from right to left. The origin of the Euclidean space from our correspondence analysis (the point at which the X and Y axes = zero) reflects the average regular equivalence profile in the network. The most extreme positive group is the core. There are two groups between the core and the origin that we’ve labeled (2) core-contenders and (3) upper tier semiperiphery. Our fourth group—the strong periphery—is at or below the origin, and the two lowest groups—(5) weak periphery and (6) weakest periphery—correspond to an increasing distance from the core (see Table A1 in the Appendix for a listing of countries by group). Thus, countries on the positive side of the origin comprise an “upper tier” and those on the negative side of the origin comprise a “lower tier” of the latent core / periphery structure.
The core group is
relatively homogenous, containing the strongest countries in the world and
headed by the
In sum, our role and position analysis results reported in Figures 1-3 and Table 2 yields a two-tiered core/periphery structure with three groups in each tier. Moreover, the increasing variance explained by the first dimension of our correspondence analysis implies that a simple core / periphery model—the single horizontal vector in Figures 1-3—accounts for variation in the role similarity between countries better as globalization proceeds, contrary to expectations from a growing body of literature in economics and sociology that suggest a more complex, differentiated or less hierarchical overall structure.
[Table 3: Average yearly GDP per capita growth by group, about here]
Where do rapidly growing countries reside in the structure of the IDL? Recall the three hypotheses developed above: the “enhanced welfare” view of the world economy suggests that there should be zero mean differences across positions in the IDL, whereas two political economy views predict either a positive-linear association, or a non-linear association. As a first approximation in adjudicating between these hypotheses, we calculate the average economic growth rate for each of our six groups from 1965 to 1980, and 1980 to 2000. As Table 3 suggests, there are two key points worth emphasizing. First, in neither period was the greatest economic growth in the core of the IDL. Rather, the most rapidly growing countries are found in our core-contending and upper-tier semi-peripheral groups. In fact, the already high growth observed in our core-contending group is actually attenuated by the inclusion of the already wealthy / developed European countries in the second period, in which the average growth for the non-European core contenders was 5.23 percent per year. On the other hand, our three peripheral groups grow the slowest in both periods, two had less than 1 percent annual growth in the second period, and one had negative growth in the second period.
In sum, the hierarchical structure of the IDL appears to have a nonlinear association with economic growth that is skewed toward the upper tier: peripheral countries in the IDL grew the slowest and the middling upper tier countries outperformed everyone.[8] This non-linear relationship between growth trends and IDL position is entirely consistent with the notion that, in the Kondratieff B phase of the period under study, the “intermediate elements” gain the most economic ground, while the “periphery” gains the least.[9]
While this growth summary suggests
that the non-linear hypothesis is most consistent with observed growth trends,
it remains to be seen whether or not this apparent association holds net of
common growth mechanisms that may also differentiate among these cases. Thus, we regress economic growth on dummy
variables for the core, periphery (semiperiphery is the excluded category), a
baseline model of secondary education, trade openness, population growth and
initial GDP per capita, along with our institutional-regional and temporal
fixed effects.[10] We use one-tailed tests for significance
because of the directional nature of the non-linear hypothesis.
[Table 4 about here]
Table 4 reports the
unstandardized regression coefficients for a baseline regression of economic
growth on the core, periphery and temporal fixed effects. As model 1 shows with respect to the baseline
association, the semiperiphery grows significantly faster than does the
periphery, while the growth difference between the core and the semiperiphery
is in the expected direction but just under significance at the conventional
.05 level (p<.06). As discussed
above, the semi-peripheral group’s growth is somewhat slowed by the inclusion
of the western European semiperiphery.
Thus, model 2 controls for this group of countries, which increases the
growth difference between the semiperiphery and both the core and periphery,
which are both in the expected direction and significant at conventional
levels. Model 3 includes all of the
control variables. Compared to
While the above models provide empirical support for the non-linear hypothesis concerning the relationship between position in the IDL and economic growth, the third part of this analysis assesses the competing hypotheses concerning the effect of IDL mobility on growth, and whether or not differential patterns of mobility explain the growth divergence observed above with respect to the periphery and semiperiphery.
While Table 2 supports previous studies in verifying the conformity of the global trade network to a core/periphery structure and suggests some polarizing tendencies, it cannot identify variation in mobility across positions of the IDL, or assess the association between mobility and growth. In order to compare the amount of upward mobility in each zone of the IDL, we start by measuring the average distance between each group and the core. In order to measure distance, we use the correspondence analysis results to measure the distance between each country and the center point of the core group in Figures 1-3 with , where is the average first dimensional coordinate for all core countries at time t, and xit is the first dimensional coordinate for country i at time t.[11] We use this distance measure to gauge the mobility of each non-core country over time with the following equation:
, (3)
where is the average of all mobility during period k. Thus, mobility is simply the distance between country i and the center of the core group at time 2, minus the same distance at time 1, expressed as a percentage of the distance at time 1 relative to the global mean.[12]
[Table 5: Structural Convergence / Divergence about here]
Recall the essence of the debate over mobility: mobility is rare / common and is / is not consistent with economic growth. Table 5 shows the average mobility scores for each group, and reveals a pattern consistent with that observed in Table 2: neither straightforward convergence nor divergence within the IDL.[13] As with the growth analysis above, dynamism in terms of upward mobility is clearly expressed by our non-core upper tier. Furthermore, excluding the developed Eastern and Western European countries from our core-contending group significantly increases the average mobility score.[14] Overall, the non-core upper tier decreased its distance from the core, while the weakest segments of the periphery performed the worst in terms of mobility. This begins to provide some empirical confirmation of our fifth hypothesis, that the rapid economic growth observed in our non-core upper tier groups is a function of their greater ability to move up in the IDL structure, and therefore upward mobility is a viable development strategy that is somewhat limited to countries that start out in the middle of the structure.
[Table 6 about here]
The apparent association between mobility and growth observed by juxtaposing Tables 2 and 5 suggests that the effect of mobility is significantly greater than 0, and that the mechanism driving the divergent growth of the upper-tier semiperiphery vis-à-vis the periphery lies in the upward mobility of the former. In order to test these hypotheses, we constrain the second set of regression models to non-core countries and regress economic growth on an indicator for the periphery, the baseline model identified above, along with mobility.
Table 6 reports results of regressions of economic growth on mobility, the periphery and the control model from above. Model 4 in Table 6 reproduces the full model in Table 4 (model 3) for the non-core countries in our sample in order to rule out potential sampling effects induced by the exclusion of core countries. Unsurprisingly, the results of model 4 are entirely consistent with model 3 in the sense that the periphery grows slower than the semiperiphery and the effects of the control variables are substantively identical to those estimated in model 3. Model 5 introduces mobility into the equation, but omits the periphery indicator. Consistent with the apparent association between Tables 2 and 5, and with hypothesis 3, mobility has a significantly positive effect on growth. If the divergent growth between the semiperiphery and the periphery is a function of the greater upward mobility of the former vis-à-vis the latter, we would expect the negative effect of the periphery to drop out after controlling for mobility. As model 6 shows, this is exactly the case as mobility retains its positive significance while the negative effect of the periphery becomes insignificant.
Finally, our last three models attempt to assuage concern over the potential simultaneity bias induced by modeling contemporaneous change scores on each side of the equation (i.e. regressing growth on mobility contemporaneously) by regressing growth in 1980-2000 on mobility from 1965-1980. Thus, model 7 replicates model 4 by regressing growth in 1980-2000 on the 1980 peripheral category (1980 semiperiphery excluded) with human capital, GDP per capita and trade openness measured in 1980 and population growth measured from 1980-2000. The growth deficit for the periphery vis-à-vis the semiperiphery is slightly larger in model 7 compared to model 4, and two of the regional fixed effects lose significance because of the smaller sample size. Model 8 replicates model 5 but replaces contemporaneous mobility with lagged mobility, producing a coefficient that is larger than either of the contemporaneous ones, as is its ratio to its own standard error. Thus, if simultaneity bias plagues these coefficients, it seems to create attenuation bias and thus works against significant effects. Finally, model 9 replicates model 6 with lagged mobility, and likewise shows a significantly positive effect of mobility that is larger than that obtained in model 6, as well as an insignificant difference between the periphery and semiperiphery. The robust effects of models 7-9 provide exceptionally strong evidence of the explanatory value of structural position and change, given their high level of saturation with a case to regressor ratio of less than seven. In sum, models 5-9 suggest that variation in mobility explains the differential growth we observe between the middle tier countries and their peripheral counter parts, consistent with hypothesis 4.
Debates about the impact of the structure of the world-economy on economic development are central to a sociological understanding of the wealth and poverty of nations. We summarize these debates as consisting of a fairly pessimistic view predicting a positive and monotonic relationship between structure and growth, and a more optimistic but temporally bounded view predicting a non-linear association between structure and growth. We juxtapose these structural hypotheses with the classic economic thinking of an “enhanced welfare” view of the IDL—a country’s position in the structure does not matter, but rather its ability to adjust its productive activity in congruence with its comparative advantage (Ricardo [1817] 2004) or resource and factor endowments (Evans 1995; Smith [1776] 2003). Moreover, we extend these structural intuitions to their implications for the effects of mobility within the structure of the world economy, which led to two related hypotheses. First, mobility has a positive effect on economic growth. But, second, middling countries in the IDL enjoy a greater propensity for mobility vis-à-vis the periphery, and therefore the observed growth differences between the semiperiphery and periphery are a function of the greater mobility of the former.
Our results tell us several things about the structure of the contemporary world-economy. First, the findings in Tables 3 and 4 provide no support for the “enhanced welfare” view of the international division of labor summarized by Hypothesis 0, nor for the more pessimistic position exemplified by Hypothesis 1. Rather, the most rapid economic growth accrues not to core countries, but to countries at intermediate positions in the IDL, at least in the last three and a half decades of the twentieth century. Second, rather than finding an IDL structure that is less hierarchically organized over time, we instead find that we can explain nearly all the variation in trade relationships between countries with a simple core/periphery model, the fit of which increases as “globalization” proceeds (Table 2). However, as our mobility analysis shows, the core contenders and upper-tier semiperiphery converged toward the core, but diverged from the periphery. Moreover, the apparent association between mobility and growth suggested by Tables 3 and 5, as well as the regression models in Table 6 provide support for Hypothesis 3 above: mobility has a robust positive effect on economic growth. Third, as we summarized with Hypothesis 4, the observed growth divergence between the periphery and the semiperiphery appears to be entirely a function of the greater propensity for upward mobility enjoyed by countries in the middle of the IDL vis-à-vis their peripheral counterparts.
These findings speak volumes to current debates in the literature on globalization and development. To recap, some argue that upward mobility is the best, and indeed only, strategy for long-term development (Amsden 2003; Firebaugh 2004; Gereffi and Memedovic 2003; Memedovic 2004). Others argue that the highest returns to economic activity accrue increasingly to “intangible” aspects of production processes, rather than to production itself, such that “industrial upgrading” only gives the “illusion” of development (Arrighi et al. 2003). Further, some analysts tend to argue that “upward mobility within the core/periphery hierarchy is exceedingly difficult and rare” (Mahutga 2006: 1882), while others note that even the current hegemonic core state resided in the periphery at one period in time (Chase-Dunn 1995). As a resolution to this debate, we suggest that the following generalization: (1) upward mobility is a viable path toward true development, but (2) countries in the middle tier of the IDL also share advantages vis-à-vis their peripheral counterparts with respect to upward mobility. In short, countries in the middle of the IDL have a structural advantage over those at the bottom during moments of industrial migration such as those witnessed over the course of economic globalization.
What do our findings suggest about development theory and policy? First, while the preceding text is conversant with some classic structural hypotheses from the world-systems perspective, much of our rationale for the empirical patterns above departs from the perspective. In short, we do not offer the classic exploitationist view of core / periphery linkages (see Evans and Stephens 1988; Frank 1969). Rather, we suggest that much of the explanation for the slow growth observed in the periphery lie with its exclusion from the aggregate rise in global functional integration observed over the course of the late twentieth century that led greater interdependence between core and semi-peripheral countries. In other words, as long as the behavior of capitalist firms is constrained by the need to generate profits, moments of industrial migration will tend to pass by countries that cannot offer both cheap and comparatively sophisticated production capabilities. These exclusionary tendencies may become more pronounced given recent claims that the ascendancy of two countries—China and India—may preclude the broader integration of many poor countries because they can absorb a significant portion of present and future offshoring activity at the expense of other countries (Gereffi and Memedovic 2003; Kaplinsky 2000; 1998; Schrank 2004). Thus, exclusionary tendencies in the structure of the world-economy are an important consideration in making predictions about long-term trends in the wealth and poverty of nations.
At the same time, casual observation implies that an active state played a
predominant role in the success stories of our sample. Four of the top five upwardly mobile
countries—(1)
Finally,
moving the discussion from global inequality to national development, and from
extremely difficult to measure income shares to economic growth trends, raises
the possibility of the persistent social exclusion of a significant share of
countries from the potential gains from globalization. Thus, previous studies that find declining
“total world inequality” do advance our knowledge about changes in the ability
of the world’s population to secure goods priced according to their own
domestic price structures, and do imply good news for a large proportion of the
world’s poor. However, by emphasizing a
declining trend they potentially obscure the fact that globalization may be
characterized by sluggish growth in most poor countries (Milanovic 2005), a
finding that seems to apply to a growing number of countries in the periphery
of the IDL (Pritchett 1997). Thus, while
REFRENCES
Abbot,
Jason P. 2003. Developmentalism and Dependency in
Alderson, Arthur and Jason Beckfield. 2004. “Power and Position in the World-City System.” American Journal of Sociology 109(4): 811-51.
Amsden, Alice.
2001. The Rise of “The Rest:”
Challenges to the West from Late-Industrializing Economies.
_______. 2003. “Comment: Good Bye Dependency Theory, Hello Dependency Theory.” Studies in Comparative International Development 38(1): 32-38.
Anheier, Helmut K and Jurgen Gerhards. 1991. “Literary Myths and Social Structure.” Social Forces 69(3): 811-830.
Arrighi, Giovanni, Beverly J. Silver and Benjamin D.
Brewer. 2003. “Industrial Convergence, Globalization, and
the Persistence of the North-South Divide.”
Studies in Comparative International Development 38(1): 3-31.
Bair, Jennifer.
2005. “Global Capitalism and
Commodity Chains: Looking Back, Going Forward.”
Competition and Change 9(2): 153-180.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1995. Economic Growth. McGraw Hill
Beck, Nathaniel and Jonathon N. Katz. 1995. “What to Do (and not to Do) With Time Series Cross Section Data.” American Political Science Review 89(3): 634-47.
Beckfield, Jason.
2005. The Consequences of
Regional Political and Economic Integration for Inequality and the Welfare
State in
Bhatta, Saurav Dev. 2002. “Has the Increase in World-Wide Openness to Trade Worsened Global Income Inequality?” Papers in Regional Science 81: 177-196.
Biggart, Nicole Woolsey and Mauro F. Guillen. 1999.
“Developing Difference: Social Organization and the Rise of the Auto Industries
of
Bollen, Kenneth A. 1990. “Political Democracy: Conceptual and Measurement Traps.” Studies in Comparative International Development 25(1): 7-24.
Boorman, Scott A. and Harrison White. 1976. “Social Structure from Multiple Networks. II Role Structures.” American Journal of Sociology 81(6): 1384-1446.
Borgatti, Stephen.
1994. “How to Explain
Hierarchical Clustering.” Connections
17(2): 78-80.
Borgatti, Stephen P. and Martin G.
Everett. 1999. “Models of Core/Periphery Structures.” Social Networks 21(4): 375-395.
Borgatti, Stephen P., Everett,
Martin G. and Freeman, Linton C. 2002. UCINET
for Windows: Software for Social Network Analysis. Harvard: Analytic
Technologies.
Bourguignon, Francios and
Christian Morrisson. 2002. “The Size Distribution of Income among World
Citizens, 1820-1990.” American
Economic Review 92(3): 727-44.
Boyd, John, William Fitzgerald,
and Robert J. Beck. 2006a. “Computing Core/Periphery Structures and
Permutation Tests for Social Relations Data.”
Social Networks 28(2): 165-78.
Boyd, John, William Fitzgerald,
Matthew C. Mahutga and David A. Smith.
2006b. “Computing
Continuous Core/Periphery Structures for Social Relations Data Using MINRES
SVD.” Paper presented at the 26th
annual Sunbelt Social Network Conference. Friday, April 28.
Brady, David, Jason Beckfield and Martin Seeleib-Kaiser. 2005. “Globalization and the Welfare State in Affluent Democracies, 1975-2001.” American Sociological Review 70(6): 921-948.
Brady, David and Ryan Denniston. 2006. “Economic Globalization, Industrialization and Deindustrialization in Affluent Democracies.” Social Forces 85(1): 297-329.
Breiger, Ronald.
1981. “Structures of Economic
Interdependence Among Nations.” Pp.
353-79 in Peter M Blaue and Robert K Merton (Eds.) Continuities in Structural Inquiry.
Butts, Carter T. 2006. “Exact Bounds for Degree Centralization.” Social Networks 28(4): 283-96.
Caporaso, James A. 1981. “Industrialization in the
Periphery: The Evolving Global Division of Labor.” International Studies Quarterly 25:
347-384.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher. 1998. Global
Formation: Structures of the World-Economy.
Chirot, Daniel. 1986. Social
Change in the Modern Era.
Cohen, S S., Di Minin A, Motoyama
Y, Palmberg, C. 2009. “The Persistence of Home Bias for Important
R&D in Wireless Telecom and Automobiles.”
Review of Policy Research 26(1-2): 55-76.
Crowly, Angela, James Rauch, Susanne Seagrave and David. Smith. 1998. “Quantitative Cross-National Studies of Economic Development: A Comparison of the Economics and Sociology Literatures.” Studies in Comparative International Development 33(2): 30-57.
Durkheim,
Emile. 1997. The
Division of Labor in Society.
Deyo, Frederic. 1987. The
Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism.
Dicken, Peter. 2003. Global
Shift: Reshaping the Global Economic Map in the 21st Century (Fourth
Edition).
Dowrick, Steve and Muhammad Akmal. 2005.
“Contradictory Trends in Global Income Inequality: A Tale of Two
Biases.” Review of Income and Wealth
51(2): 201-229.
Dowrick,
Steve. 2004. “Review of The New Geography of Global Income
Inequality.” Journal of Economic
Literature 42: 1122-1123.
Evans, Peter and James E. Rauch. 1999.
“Bureaucracy and Growth: A Cross-National Analysis of the Effects of
‘Weberian’ State Structures on Economic Growth.” American Sociological Review 64(5):
748-65.
Evans, Peter and John D.
Stephens. 1988. “Studying Development since the Sixties: The
Emergence of a New Comparative Political Economy.” Theory and Society 17: 713-45.
Evans, Peter. 1995. Embedded
Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton:
_______. 1979a.
Dependent Development: The
_______. 1979b. “
Faust, Katherine. 1988. "Comparison of Methods for Positional Analysis: Structural and General Equivalences." Social Networks 10:313-41.
Firebaugh, Glenn. 2004.
“Does Industrialization No Longer Benefit Poor Countries? A Comment on Arrighi, Silver, and Brewer,
2003.” Studies in Comparative
International Development 39(1): 99-105.
_______. 2003. The
New Geography of Global Income Inequality.
Firebaugh, Glenn and Brian Goesling. 2004. “Accounting for the Recent Decline in Global Income Inequality.” American Journal of Sociology 110 (2): 283-312.
Frank, Andre Gunder. 1969. Latin American:
Underdevelopment or Revolution.
Friedman,
Thomas. 2005. The World Is Flat.
Galtung,
Johan. 1971. “A Structural Theory of Imperialism.” Journal of Peace Research 2: 81-117.
Gereffi, Gary. 2009.
“Development Models and Industrial Upgrading in
_______. 1994. “The Organization of Buyer-Driven Global
Commodity Chains: How US Retailers Shape Overseas Production Networks.” In Gereffi and Korczenewics (Eds.) Commodity Chains and Global
Capitalism.
_______. 1983. The Pharmaceutical Industry and
Dependency in the
Gereffi, Gary,
John Humphrey and Timothy Sturgeon.
2005. “The Governance of Global
Value Chains.” Review of
International Political Economy 12(1): 78-104.
Gereffi, Gary and
Olga Memedovic. 2003. The Global Apparel Value Chain: What
Prospects for Upgrading by Developing Countries?
Gereffi, Gary,
John Humphrey and Timothy Sturgeon.
2001. “Introduction:
Globalization, Value Chains, and Development.:
IDS Bulletin 32(3): 1-8.
Gereffi, Gary and Miguel Korzeniewicz (Eds.) 1994. Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism.
Gereffi, Gary and Donald L. Wyman (Eds.). 1990. Manufacturing
Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and
Goesling, Brian. 2001. “Changing Income Inequalities Within and Between Nations: New Evidence.” American Sociological Review 66: 745-761.
Granovetter, Mark. 1985. “Economic Action and Social Structure: the
Problem of Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology
91(3):481-93.
_______. 1973. “The Strength of Weak Ties.” American Journal of Sociology 78(6): 1360-80
Greenacre, Michael J. 1984.
Theory and Applications of Correspondence Analysis.
Halaby, Charles. (2004) “Panel Models in Sociological Research: Theory into Practice.” Annual Review of Sociology 30: 507-544.
Heston, Alan, Robert Summers and Bettina Aten. 2002. Penn World Table Version 6.1,
Center for International Comparisons at the
Hicks, Alexander and Lane Kenworthy. 1998.
“Cooperation and Political Economic Performance in Affluent Democratic
Capitalism.” American Journal of
Sociology 130(6): 1631-72.
Hoogvelt, Ankie.
2001. Globalization and the
Post-Colonial World: The New Political Economy of Development.
Hopkins, Terrance and Immanuel Wallerstein. 1986. “Commodity Chains in the World Economy Prior to 1800.” Review 10(1): 157-70.
_______. 1977. “Patterns of Development of the Modern World-System.” Review 1(2): 11-145.
Humphrey, John and Olga Memedovic. 2003. The
Global Automotive Industry Value Chain: What Prospects for Upgrading by
Developing Countries.
IMF. 2006. Direction of Trade Statistics.
_______ 1997. World
Economic Outlook.
Islam, Nazrul. 2003.
“What Have We Learnt from the Convergence Debate?” Journal of Economic Surveys 17(3):
309-362.
Johnson, Stephen
C. 1967.
“Hierarchical Clustering Schemes.”
Psychometrica 32: 241-53.
Jones, Charles. 1997. “Convergence Revisited.” Journal of Economic Growth 2: 131–53.
Kaplinsky, Raphael.
2005. Globalization, Poverty
and Inequality.
_______. 2001. “Is globalization all its cracked up to be?” Review of International Political Economy 8(1): 45-65.
_______. 2000. “Globalisation and Unequalization: What Can Be Learned from Value Chain Analysis?” Journal of Development Studies 37(2): 117-146.
_______. 1998. “Globalization, Industrialization and
Sustainable Growth: The Pursuit of the Nth Rent” IDS Discussion Paper 365
Kick, Edward L., Byron L. Davis, M Lehtinen and Thomas J Burnes. 2000. “World-System Position, National Political Characteristics and Economic Development Outcomes.” Journal of Political and Military Sociology 28(1): 131-155.
Kick, Edward L. and Byron L. Davis. 2001. “World-System Structure and Change: An Analysis of Global Networks and Economic Growth Across Two Time Periods.” American Behavioral Scientist 44(10): 1567-1578.
Kim,
Sangmoon and Eui-Hang Shin. 2002. “A Longitudinal Analysis of Globalization and
Regionalization in International Trade: A Social Network Approach.” Social Forces 81(2): 445-71.
Kikhanov, Yuri and Michael Ward. 2001.
“Evolution of the Global Distribution of Income, 1970-1999.” August 2001 draft.
http://www.eclac.cl/povertystatistcs/documentos/dikhanov.pdf.
Koop, Gary; Jacek Osiewalski, and Mark Steel. 1995. “Measuring the Sources of Output
Growth in a Panel of countries.” CORE Discussion Paper, number 9542.
Korzeniewicz, Roberto Patricio and Timothy Patrick Moran. 1997. “World-Economic Trends in the Distribution of Income, 1965-1992.” American Journal of Sociology 102(4): 1000-1039.
Krueger, Ann O. 1998. “Why Trade Liberalization is Good for Growth.” The Economic Journal 108: 1513-1522.
Maddison, Angus.
2001. The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective.
Mahutga, Matthew C. 2006. “The Persistence of Structural Inequality? A Network Analysis of International Trade, 1965-2000.” Social Forces 84(4): 1863-89.
Marx, Karl 1977. A Contribution
to the Critique of Political Economy.
Maxton, Graeme P. and John
Wormald. 2004. Time for a Model Change: Re-engineering
the Global Automotive Industry.
Melchior, Arne, and Kjetil
Telle. 2001. “Global Income Distribution, 1965-1998:
Convergence and Marginalization.” Forum
for Development Studies 1 (June): 75-98.
Memedovic, Olga.
2004. Inserting Local
Industries in Global Value Chains and Global Production Networks.
Milanovic, Branco. 2006.
“Global Income Inequality: What It Is And Why It Matters.” Working Paper, World Bank Development
Research Group. http://www.ethics.harvard.edu/download/milanovic1.pdf
_______. 2005. Worlds
Apart: Measuring International and Global Inequality. Princeton:
Mullins, Nicholas C.,
Nemeth, Roger J. and David A. Smith. 1985. "International Trade and World System Structure: A Multiple Network Analysis." Review 8(4): 517-160.
Ohmae,
Kenichi. 1985. Triad Power, the Coming Shape of Global
Competition.
Parente,
Steven L. and Edward C. Prescott.
2000. Barriers to Riches.
Pritchett, Lant. 1997.
“Divergence, Big Time.” Journal
of Economic Perspectives 11(3): 3-17.
Ricardo,
David. [1817] 2004. The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation.
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. 2002.
“The Disturbing ‘Rise’ of World Income Inequality.” NBER Working
Paper No. 8904, April. www.nber.org
Schrank, Andrew. 2004.
“Ready to Wear Development? Foreign
Investment, Technology Transfer, and Learning by Watching in the Apparel
Trade.” Social Forces 83(1):
123-56.
Schultz, T. Paul. 1998.
“Inequality in the Distribution of Personal Income in the World: How it
is Changing and Why.” Journal of Population
Economics 11: 307-344.
Sheehey, Edmund J. 1996.
“The Growing Gap Between Rich and Poor Countries: A Proposed
Explanation.” World Development
24(8): 1379-1384.
Smith,
Adam. [1776] 2003. The Wealth of Nations.
Smith, David A and Roger J.
Nemeth. 1988. “Research Note: An Empirical Analysis of
Commodity Exchange in the International Economy: 1965-1980.” International
Studies Quarterly 32: 227-240.
Smith, David A and Douglas R.
White. 1992. “Structure and Dynamics of the Global Economy: Network Analysis of
International Trade 1965-1980. Social
Forces 70(4): 857-893.
Snijders, Tom and Stephen
Borgatti. 1999. “Non-Parametric Standard Errors and Tests for
Network Statistics.” Connections 22(2):
161-70.
Snyder, David and Edward L. Kick.
1979. “Structural Position in the World System and Economic Growth, 1955-1970:
A Multiple-Network Analysis of Transnational Interactions.” American Journal of Sociology 84(5):
1096-1126.
Solow, Robert M. 1956.
“A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70(1):
65-94.
Swan,
Trevor W. 1956. “Economic Growth and Capital
Accumulation.” Economic Record
32: 334-361.
Taylor, Peter J. 1988. “World-System Analysis and Regional Geography.” Professional Geographer 40: 259-65.
Temple, Jonathan. 1999. “The New Growth Evidence.” Journal of Economic Literature 37(1): 112-156.
Thun, Eric. 2008.
“The Globalization of Production.”
Pp. 346-372 in John Ravenhill (Ed.) Global Political Economy.
Total Economy
Database. 2006. The Conference Board and Groningen Growth and
United
Nations. 2006. COMTRADE.
_______. Various Years. Statistical Yearbook.
_______. 1963.
“Commodity Indexes for the Standard International Trade Classification,
Revision 1.” Statistical Papers
M:38(II).
Van Rossem, Ronan. 1996. “The World-System Paradigm as General Theory of Development: A Cross-National Test.” American Sociological Review 61(3): 508-27.
Wade, Robert Hunter. 2004. “Is Globalization Reducing Poverty and Inequality?” World Development 32(4): 567-89.
Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1998.
“The So-Called Asian Crisis: Geopolitics in the Long Duree.”
_______. 1989 The Modern
World-System III.
_______. 1979. The Capitalist World-Economy.
_______. 1976. “Semi-peripheral Countries and the Contemporary World-Crisis.” Theory and Society 3: 461-484.
Wasserman, Stanley and
Katherine Faust. 1999. Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications.
Weber, Max. 1978. Economy and
Society, Vol 1 and 2.
Weller, Susan and A. Kimball Romney 1990. Metric Scaling: Correspondence Analysis.
A
Western, Bruce.
1997. Between Class and Market: Postwar Unionization in the Capitalist
Democracies.
White, Douglas R.
1984. REGE: A regular graph
equivalence algorithm for computing role distances prior to block
modeling. Unpublished manuscript.
White Douglas R. and Karl P. Reitz. 1983. “Graph and semi-group homomorphisms on networks of relations.” Social Networks 6: 193-235.
White, Harrison C, Scott A. Boorman and Ronald L.
Breiger. 1976. “Social Structure from Multiple Networks:
Wood, A. 1994. North—South Trade, Employment and
Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World.
Wooldridge, Jeffrey M.
2002. Econometric Analysis of
Cross Section and Panel Data.
World Bank.
2006. World Development
Indicators.
World Bank.
2002. EdStats.
TABLES
Table 1: UN Commodity Categories
Classified in Relational Categories from Smith and Nemeth (1988)
|
1) High Tech/Heavy Manufacturing |
58) Plastic Materials, Regenerated Cellulose
and Artificial Resins |
69) Manufactures of Metal |
71) Machinery – nonelectrical |
2) Sophisticated Extractive |
25) Pulp and waste paper |
34) Gas, natural and manufactured |
64) Paper, paperboard, and manufactures
thereof. |
3) Simple Extractive |
04) Cereal and cereal preparations |
22) Oil seeds, oil nuts and oil kernels |
41) Animal oils and fats |
4) Low Wage/Light Manufactures |
83) Travel bags, handbags, and similar
containers |
84) Clothing |
85) Footwear |
5) Animal products and byproducts |
01) Meat and meat preparations |
02) Dairy products and bird’s eggs |
29) Crude animal and vegetable materials |
Table 2: Explained variance of regular equivalencies by correspondence analysis across dimension and year.
Dimensions |
Year |
||
1965 |
1980 |
2000 |
|
Dimension
1 |
|
|
|
Singular
Value |
0.138 |
0.124 |
0.123 |
Explained
Variance* |
90.50% |
93.50% |
96% |
Dimension
2 |
|
|
|
Singular
Value |
0.026 |
0.02 |
0.014 |
Explained
Variance* |
3.20% |
2.40% |
1.20% |
Dimension
3 |
|
|
|
Singular
Value |
0.02 |
0.016 |
0.013 |
Explained
Variance* |
2% |
1.50% |
1.10% |
Dimension
4 |
|
|
|
Singular
Value |
0.015 |
0.009 |
0.007 |
Explained
Variance* |
1% |
0.50% |
0.30% |
Dimension
5 |
|
|
|
Singular
Value |
0.009 |
0.007 |
0.006 |
Explained
Variance* |
0.40% |
0.30% |
0.20% |
Notes: *Explained variance is calculated
with equation 4 |
|
Table 4: Unstandardized Coefficients from Regression of Economic Growth on Select Independent Variables.
|
1 |
2 |
3 |
Structure
a |
|
|
|
Core |
-.902 |
-1.280* |
-2.739*** |
|
(.581) |
(.707) |
(.844) |
Periphery |
-2.628*** |
-3.007*** |
-1.428* |
|
(.581) |
(.704) |
(.691) |
European Semiperiphery |
--- |
-1.383* |
-2.802*** |
|
|
(.761) |
(.824) |
Institutional
/ Regional Fixed Effects b |
|
|
|
West |
--- |
--- |
-.790 |
|
|
|
(.862) |
|
--- |
--- |
-2.952** |
|
|
|
(1.102) |
|
--- |
--- |
-2.498** |
|
|
|
(.991) |
Central
and Eastern |
--- |
--- |
-4.474*** |
|
|
|
(.987) |
|
--- |
--- |
-2.875*** |
|
|
|
(.871) |
Neo-Classical
Growth Model |
|
|
|
Initial
GDP per capita |
--- |
--- |
-.382 |
|
|
|
(1.060) |
Human
Capital |
--- |
--- |
.003 |
|
|
|
(.018) |
Trade
Openness |
--- |
--- |
-.013** |
|
|
|
(.005) |
Population
Growth |
--- |
--- |
-.738** |
|
|
|
(.306) |
Temporal
Fixed Effects |
|
|
|
1965-1980 |
1.738*** |
1.693*** |
1.564*** |
|
(.381) |
(.384) |
(.393) |
|
|
|
|
Constant |
3.178*** |
3.579*** |
8.488** |
|
(.519) |
(.656) |
(3.272) |
|
|
|
|
R2 |
.212 |
.224 |
.415 |
|
|
|
|
N |
188 |
188 |
188 |
|
|
Mobility |
|
Major Group |
Minor Group |
1965-1980 |
1980-2000 |
Semiperiphery |
Core-Contenders |
0.059 |
0.027 |
|
|
|
|
Upper
Tier Semiperiphery |
0.126 |
0.178 |
|
|
|
|
|
Periphery |
Strong Periphery |
-0.056 |
-0.021 |
|
|
|
|
Weak
Periphery |
-0.034 |
-0.005 |
|
|
|
|
|
Weakest
Periphery |
-0.083 |
-0.095 |
Notes: Mobility measured with the average of equation 3 for each group, excluding outliers.
Table 6: Unstandardized Coefficients from Regression of Economic Growth on Mobility and Select Independent Variables, 1965-2000.
|
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
Structure
a |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Mobility |
--- |
3.717* |
3.293** |
--- |
4.734*** |
4.193*** |
|
|
(1.604) |
(1.160) |
|
(1.260) |
(1.241) |
Periphery |
-1.426* |
--- |
-.874 |
-1.833* |
--- |
-.984 |
|
(.694) |
|
(.617) |
(.860) |
|
(.768) |
European Semiperiphery |
-2.840*** |
-1.534* |
-1.886* |
-4.432*** |
-2.711* |
-3.243** |
|
(.832) |
(.815) |
(.867) |
(1.119) |
(1.154) |
(1.092) |
Institutional
/ Regional Fixed Effects b |
|
|
|
|
|
|
West |
-.862 |
-.854 |
-.930 |
-.377 |
-.492 |
-.397 |
|
(.869) |
(.834) |
(.819) |
(1.145) |
(1.097) |
(1.057) |
|
-2.903** |
-2.621** |
-2.160* |
-2.059 |
-2.175* |
-1.588 |
|
(1.103) |
(.898) |
(1.067) |
(1.369) |
(1.122) |
(1.282) |
|
-2.428** |
-2.302** |
-1.975* |
-1.917 |
-1.836 |
-1.375 |
|
(.994) |
(.935) |
(.972) |
(1.479) |
(1.385) |
(1.480) |
Central
and Eastern |
-4.543*** |
-3.089** |
-3.439*** |
-7.772*** |
-5.489*** |
-6.018*** |
|
(.989) |
(1.071) |
(1.037) |
(1.822) |
(1.730) |
(1.723) |
|
-2.906*** |
-3.069*** |
-2.750*** |
-3.684*** |
-3.893*** |
-3.555*** |
|
(.874) |
(.708) |
(.839) |
(.976) |
(.822) |
(.947) |
Neo-Classical
Growth Model |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Initial
GDP per capita |
-.197 |
-.150 |
-.078 |
.360 |
.369 |
.327 |
|
(1.085) |
(.959) |
(1.026) |
(1.449) |
(1.304) |
(1.361) |
Human
Capital |
.000 |
.003 |
.003 |
-.014 |
-.018 |
-.016 |
|
(.019) |
(.018) |
(.018) |
(.024) |
(.024) |
(.024) |
Trade
Openness |
-.013** |
-.010* |
-.011** |
-.017** |
-.012* |
-.014** |
|
(.005) |
(.005) |
(.005) |
(.006) |
(.005) |
(.005) |
Population
Growth |
-.809** |
-.867*** |
-.854** |
-1.495*** |
-1.492*** |
-1.478*** |
|
(.311) |
(.258) |
(.290) |
(.446) |
(.410) |
(.411) |
Temporal
Fixed Effects |
|
|
|
|
|
|
1965-1980 |
1.611*** |
1.845*** |
1.781*** |
--- |
--- |
--- |
|
(.421) |
(.467) |
(.428) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Constant |
8.058** |
6.476* |
6.687* |
8.646 |
7.140 |
7.696 |
|
(3.321) |
(2.998) |
(3.118) |
(4.770) |
(3.897) |
(4.071) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
R2 |
.420 |
.448 |
.455 |
.522 |
.571 |
.579 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
N |
167 c |
167 c |
167 c |
83 c |
83 c |
83 c |
Notes: Models 4-6 report unstandardized coefficients from
OLS regressions where periods 1965-1980 and 1980-2000 are pooled and all
independent variables are measured at the initial year except population
growth, which is contemporaneous.
Numbers in parentheses are panel corrected standard errors. Models 7-9
report unstandardized coefficients from OLS regressions where mobility is
measured from 1965-1980, economic and population growth are measured from
1980-2000, and all else are measured at 1980.
Numbers in parentheses are robust standard errors. *p<.05; **p<.01; ***p<.001
(one-tailed test except the constant). a semiperiphry is the excluded category;
b
FIGURES:
Figure 1: Superimposition of Hierarchical Clustering and Correspondence Analysis of Regular Equivalencies, 1965.
Figure 2: Superimposition
of Hierarchical Clustering and Correspondence Analysis of Regular
Equivalencies, 1980.
Figure 3:
Superimposition of Hierarchical Clustering and Correspondence
Analysis of Regular Equivalencies, 2000.
APPENDIX
Table A1: Country
by IDL Equivalence Group and Region.
Group* |
|
Country and Rank in 1965 |
Group* |
|||||||
1965 |
1980 |
2000 |
|
1965 |
1980 |
2000 |
||||
1 |
|
1 |
1 |
1 |
|
48 |
|
4 |
3 |
3 |
2 |
France (W) |
1 |
1 |
1 |
|
59 |
|
4 |
3 |
4 |
3 |
|
1 |
1 |
1 |
|
49 |
|
4 |
4 |
4 |
4 |
|
1 |
1 |
1 |
|
53 |
|
4 |
4 |
4 |
5 |
|
1 |
1 |
1 |
|
55 |
|
4 |
4 |
4 |
6 |
|
1 |
1 |
1 |
|
58 |
|
4 |
4 |
4 |
7 |
|
1 |
1 |
1 |
|
60 |
|
4 |
4 |
4 |
9 |
|
1 |
1 |
1 |
|
50 |
|
4 |
4 |
5 |
11 |
|
1 |
1 |
1 |
|
54 |
|
4 |
4 |
5 |
8 |
|
1 |
1 |
2 |
|
61 |
|
4 |
4 |
5 |
10 |
|
1 |
2 |
2 |
|
62 |
|
4 |
4 |
5 |
21 |
|
2 |
2 |
1 |
|
51 |
|
4 |
5 |
4 |
12 |
|
2 |
2 |
2 |
|
63 |
|
4 |
5 |
4 |
13 |
|
2 |
2 |
2 |
|
52 |
|
4 |
5 |
5 |
14 |
|
2 |
2 |
2 |
|
57 |
|
4 |
5 |
5 |
15 |
|
2 |
2 |
2 |
|
64 |
|
4 |
5 |
5 |
16 |
|
2 |
2 |
2 |
|
65 |
|
4 |
5 |
5 |
17 |
|
2 |
2 |
2 |
|
66 |
|
4 |
5 |
5 |
18 |
|
2 |
2 |
2 |
|
56 |
|
4 |
6 |
6 |
19 |
|
2 |
2 |
2 |
|
70 |
|
5 |
4 |
4 |
20 |
|
2 |
2 |
2 |
|
73 |
|
5 |
4 |
5 |
22 |
|
2 |
2 |
2 |
|
78 |
|
5 |
5 |
3 |
23 |
|
2 |
2 |
3 |
|
67 |
|
5 |
5 |
5 |
24 |
|
3 |
2 |
2 |
|
68 |
Trinidad/Tobago (L) |
5 |
5 |
5 |
25 |
|
3 |
2 |
2 |
|
71 |
|
5 |
5 |
5 |
26 |
|
3 |
2 |
2 |
|
72 |
|
5 |
5 |
5 |
29 |
|
3 |
2 |
2 |
|
74 |
|
5 |
5 |
5 |
32 |
|
3 |
2 |
2 |
|
75 |
Jordan (ME) |
5 |
5 |
5 |
36 |
|
3 |
2 |
2 |
|
76 |
|
5 |
5 |
5 |
28 |
|
3 |
2 |
3 |
|
77 |
|
5 |
5 |
5 |
30 |
|
3 |
3 |
2 |
|
69 |
|
5 |
6 |
5 |
31 |
|
3 |
3 |
2 |
|
79 |
|
5 |
6 |
6 |
37 |
|
3 |
3 |
2 |
|
91 |
|
6 |
5 |
5 |
27 |
|
3 |
3 |
3 |
|
80 |
|
6 |
5 |
6 |
34 |
|
3 |
3 |
3 |
|
82 |
|
6 |
5 |
6 |
40 |
|
3 |
3 |
3 |
|
88 |
|
6 |
6 |
5 |
41 |
|
3 |
3 |
3 |
|
90 |
|
6 |
6 |
5 |
33 |
|
3 |
3 |
4 |
|
81 |
|
6 |
6 |
6 |
42 |
|
3 |
4 |
3 |
|
83 |
|
6 |
6 |
6 |
35 |
|
3 |
4 |
4 |
|
84 |
|
6 |
6 |
6 |
38 |
|
3 |
4 |
4 |
|
85 |
|
6 |
6 |
6 |
39 |
|
3 |
4 |
5 |
|
86 |
|
6 |
6 |
6 |
44 |
|
4 |
3 |
4 |
|
87 |
|
6 |
6 |
6 |
45 |
|
4 |
4 |
4 |
|
89 |
|
6 |
6 |
6 |
46 |
|
4 |
4 |
4 |
|
92 |
|
6 |
6 |
6 |
47 |
|
4 |
4 |
4 |
|
93 |
|
6 |
6 |
6 |
43 |
|
4 |
5 |
5 |
|
94 |
|
6 |
6 |
6 |
Notes: Countries arranged from highest to lowest across all
periods. *Group 1 = Core; Group 2 =
Core-Contenders; Group 3 = Upper Tier Semiperiphery; Group 4 = Strong
Periphery; Group = Weak Periphery; Group 6 = Weakest Periphery. Af = Africa, As
= Asia; CEE = Central and Eastern Europe; L = Latin America; ME =
Table A2:
Correlation Coefficients for Variables Included in Analyses.
|
|
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
11 |
12 |
13 |
14 |
15 |
16 |
1 |
Economic
Growth |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
2 |
Core |
0.077 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
3 |
Semiperiphery |
0.337 |
-0.249 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
4 |
Periphery |
-0.368 |
-0.399 |
-0.789 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
5 |
European Semiperiphery |
0.040 |
-0.112 |
0.450 |
-0.355 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
6 |
Mobility |
0.383 |
--- |
0.255 |
-0.255 |
-0.197 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
7 |
GDP per
capita |
0.039 |
0.426 |
0.140 |
-0.403 |
0.318 |
0.011 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
8 |
Secondary
Education Enrollment |
0.128 |
0.425 |
0.257 |
-0.513 |
0.366 |
0.021 |
0.751 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
9 |
Trade
Openness |
-0.209 |
0.004 |
0.001 |
-0.003 |
-0.134 |
-0.041 |
0.027 |
0.037 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
10 |
Population
Growth |
-0.304 |
-0.392 |
-0.298 |
0.531 |
-0.363 |
-0.009 |
-0.343 |
-0.586 |
-0.011 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
11 |
West |
0.147 |
0.651 |
0.130 |
-0.536 |
0.402 |
-0.021 |
0.577 |
0.603 |
0.028 |
-0.561 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
12 |
|
0.474 |
-0.035 |
0.342 |
-0.302 |
-0.121 |
0.430 |
-0.099 |
0.037 |
-0.096 |
0.012 |
-0.132 |
|
|
|
|
|
13 |
|
-0.261 |
-0.184 |
-0.337 |
0.436 |
-0.164 |
-0.290 |
-0.553 |
-0.507 |
0.154 |
0.306 |
-0.283 |
-0.199 |
|
|
|
|
14 |
|
-0.187 |
-0.148 |
-0.135 |
0.222 |
-0.132 |
-0.046 |
-0.016 |
-0.122 |
0.005 |
0.457 |
-0.157 |
-0.160 |
-0.218 |
|
|
|
15 |
Central
and Eastern |
-0.041 |
-0.064 |
0.259 |
-0.204 |
0.154 |
-0.201 |
0.048 |
0.156 |
-0.067 |
-0.232 |
-0.099 |
-0.070 |
-0.094 |
-0.076 |
|
|
16 |
|
-0.110 |
-0.184 |
-0.116 |
0.227 |
-0.164 |
0.133 |
0.037 |
-0.123 |
-0.092 |
0.034 |
-0.283 |
-0.199 |
-0.270 |
-0.218 |
-0.094 |
|
17 |
1965-1980 |
0.269 |
0.017 |
0.000 |
-0.011 |
-0.056 |
0.001 |
-0.182 |
-0.390 |
-0.338 |
0.132 |
--- |
--- |
--- |
--- |
--- |
--- |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Mean |
2.479 |
0.112 |
0.330 |
0.559 |
0.090 |
0.000 |
3.611 |
41.870 |
61.233 |
1.964 |
--- |
--- |
--- |
--- |
--- |
--- |
|
SD |
3.274 |
0.316 |
0.471 |
0.498 |
0.288 |
0.237 |
0.428 |
28.572 |
38.567 |
1.255 |
--- |
--- |
--- |
--- |
--- |
--- |
Table A3: Variable Measurement and Source.
Variable |
Measurement |
Source |
Position
in the IDL |
Role and
Position analysis of five matrices at each period. Each of the five N x N matrices were
obtained by cell wise summation of the three UN classified commodity groups
within the five broad relational categories of Smith and Nemeth (1988) in
Table 1. |
UN
COMTRADE |
Mobility
in the IDL |
Change in
distance from core group as a percent of initial distance, minus the global
average for each period. |
Correspondence
analysis of regular equivalence matrix obtained from UN COMTRADE data. |
Economic
Growth |
Gross
Domestic Product Per Capita adjusted to achieve purchasing power parity
(PPP). Growth measured as a percent
change: (GDPpct1
- GDPpcto) / GDPpcto Yeart1-Yeart0 |
The
majority of these data (83%) come from the Penn World Tables (Heston, Summers
and Atea 2002), and the remaining 17% of missing cases were obtained from
Milanovich (2005) and the Total Economy Database. Growth rates are highly correlated across
GDP per capita sources. Nonetheless,
auxiliary analyses including dummy variable for source rule out bias owing to
data source. |
Initial
GDP per capita |
Gross
domestic product per capita adjusted to achieve purchasing power parity
(PPP), logged for skew with the base 10 logarithm. |
The
majority of these data (83%) come from the Penn World Tables (Heston, Summers
and Atea 2002), and the remaining 17% were obtained from Milanovich (2005)
and the Total Economy Database. |
Human
Capital |
Students enrolled in
secondary education / school aged population |
World
Bank (2006), UN Statistical Yearbook (Various Years) |
Trade
Openness |
(Imports
+ Exports) / GDP |
IMF
(2006) / World Bank (2006) |
Population
Growth |
Populationt2
- Populationt1 |
World
Bank (2006) |
Institutional
/ Regional Variation |
Dummy
variables for West, Asia, Africa, Central and Eastern Europe, Latin America,
and the |
Regional
placements appear in Table A1. |
[1] In the most detailed
analysis of weighted international inequality to date, Milanovic (2005) shows
that the declining gap between the income of China, on the one hand, and the
six largest OECD countries, along with Brazil Mexico and Russia, on the other,
explain all of the observed decline in inequality between 1978 and 2000
(Chapter 8).
[2] Given an N х N matrix where cell ij represents the export from actor i to actor j, one can use either actor i’s reported exports, or actor j’s reported imports to measure j’s import from i, or equivalently, i’s export to j. While export and import data are very highly correlated, reported imports tend to be more accurate because of the care taken by state agencies to record imports accurately for the purpose of tariffs (Durand 1953). Thus, we use reported imports, measured in current US dollars, to measure both imports and exports between each country.
[3] We want to state clearly that our role and position analysis is “agnostic” with respect to prior expectations as to what types of patterns we should observe across commodity groupings, and is therefore amenable to the notion that “core” activities vary both across industries and over time. Indeed, unreported analyses demonstrates that our method detects the fact that “core” activities change over time, with garment manufacturing becoming increasingly peripheralized—moving to the periphery—during the period studied (Gereffi 1994). In the interest of space we do not include these analyses but make them available upon request.
[4] Two
countries (
[5] Some may argue that domestic investment should be part of a baseline model of economic growth. To accommodate this concern, we estimated all models including domestic investment, which was only available for approximately eighty percent of our sample. All but one of models that included initial level of domestic investment were substantively identical to those presented here. In the one model where differences were observed, coefficients performed identically but with less power, and we found that the weakened significance is attributable to sampling effects rather than omitted variable bias (i.e. a model that included only those cases with non-missing data on investment was identical to that which included investment). These analyses are available upon request.
[6] Some authors
estimate random effects models (REM) owing to some of the concerns we raise
here. While we do not see the added
value in the REM approach when the assumption of uncorrelated unit effects is
not met, and when we take alternative precautions, we did estimate a series of
random effects models as added robustness test.
Unsurprisingly
given the amount of variation residing between cases in our data, the
coefficients and standard errors from the REM models we estimated were almost
identical to those we report. These
analyses are available upon request.
[7] Many methods of evaluating a set of cut points have been suggested (Wasserman and Faust 1999). For our purposes, we consider the robust correspondence analysis solution as a benchmark against which to evaluate our complete link hierarchical clustering groups. Because the first dimension of our correspondence analysis explains 90 to 96 percent of the variance in regular equivalence between countries, this provides a straightforward evaluation of fit—the amount of variation on the first dimension we can explain with our group assignments. These values are: 1965 = 94.9%, 1980 = 92.7%, and 2000 = 93.6%.
[8] These interpretations only hold true if there is relative stability in the members of each group over time. If poor countries move to the upper tier, and thus enjoy the faster economic growth of the upper tier, than there is little reason to suggest a diverging growth pattern. Table A2 in the Appendix gives a correlation matrix, and shows that the correlation between the groups for 1965 and 1980 is .93, while that between 1980 and 2000 (five years longer) is .94.
[9] It is very unlikely that
this is simply a sampling effect. In a
study of the data available in the Penn World Tables, Lant Pritchett notes that
“Of the 108 developing countries…11 grew faster than 4.2 per annum over the
1960 to 1990 period…sixteen developing countries had negative growth over the
1960-1990 period…Another 28 nations…had growth rates of per capita GDP less
than .5 percent per annum from 1960 to 1990…and 40 developing nations…had
growth rates less than 1 percent per annum” (Pritchett 1997: 14).
[10] Our decision to combine the
semiperiphery and periphery into single indicators stems from two issues. First, the small number of countries in some
of the groups increases the standard error for the difference between their
growth and a comparison group asymptotically, which raises the probability of a
type II error. Second, preliminary
analyses reveal that there were not significant growth differences between any
of the semi-peripheral or peripheral groups, but rather that the differences
were between the major categories.
[11] This corresponds to an
alternative operationalization alluded to by Borgatti and Everett (1999) “In a
Euclidean representation, [“peripheralness”] would correspond to distance from
the centroid of a single point cloud” (Borgatti and Everett 1999: pp. 387, also
see Boyd, Fitzgerald and Beck 2006; Boyd et al. 2006a; 2006b).
[12]
Subtracting the average controls for the fact that the overall density of trade
has dramatically increased since 1965, and in this way identifies upwardly
mobile individual countries net of the “density effect” (see Butts 2006 and
Mahutga 2006 for a full discussion).
Note that (3) precludes the identification of mobility for core
countries. We opt for this preclusion
because 1) by definition, upward mobility is almost impossible once in the core
and 2) we rely on reasoning drawn from the seminal work of Borgatti and
[13] In
order to make sure that outliers did not unduly influence our summary measure
for each group, we utilized the applications available in SYSTAT to identify
outliers and influential cases. We found
several outliers: in the 1965-1980 period, we found one positive outlier (
[14] The average upward mobility for our non-European core contenders in the 1965-2000 period is .418, while that observed in 1980-2000 is .272. On the other hand, the developed, European core-contenders display downward mobility in both periods, which is consistent with a picture of the two groups switching places in the overall distribution of “coreness.”
[15] Understandably,
one may wonder how population figures into this analysis. Unreported analyses show that while the vast
majority of the world’s population lives in the fast growth middling positions
in the IDL, we also find that the slow growing peripheral groups are the only
positions in the structure that experience a secularly increasing share of the
world population (rising from 9 percent to 18 percent in the period under
study), while core and semi-peripheral positions contain a declining share of
the world’s population. Thus, despite
the huge population shares in the middle tier, an increasing
number of countries / human beings are slipping into a slow growing periphery
over time.