Last of the hegemons:
Chris Chase-Dunn, Roy Kwon,
Kirk Lawrence and Hiroko Inoue
Institute for Research on World-Systems
University of California-Riverside
v.11/15/2010 9828 words
Abstract: This paper
reexamines quantitative indicators of national economic and military power
since 1820 and discusses their meanings for the trajectory of power
concentration in the contemporary world-system. We discuss the causes of
For presentation at the session at the
Social Science History Association meeting on “The United States in Decline:
Why It Is Happening and What It Means” November 18, 12
IROWS Working Paper # 65 https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows65/irows65.htm
*Thanks to William R. Thompson for seapower estimates from 1945 to 2007) and to Peter J. Taylor for “last of the hegemons.”
All
hierarchical human systems exhibit a sequence of concentration and
deconcentration of power, but the nature of power and the causes of rise and
fall evolve as world-systems get larger and more complex. The modern
world-system has experienced a series of episodes of global governance
organized around the predominance of a hegemonic national state that has
enjoyed a temporary superiority in economic centrality and political/military
power and influence: the United Provinces of the Netherlands in the 17th
century, the United Kingdom of Great Britain in the 19th century and
the United States of America in the 20th century. All three were
former semiperipheral polities that rose to core status and then took up the
role of political and economic hegemony.
This
sequence, along with the institutionalization and spread of the international
system of sovereign states and the rise of supranational political institutions
since the Napoleonic Wars, constitutes the evolution of global governance as it
has occurred in the modern system. Figure 1 uses ratios of national Gross
Domestic Product(GDP) per capita to the average world GDP per capita to
illustrate the three hegemonies and to show the relative trajectories of
Figure 1: Three Hegemonies: GDP per capita as a ratio
to world GDP per capita 1500CE- 1998CE, Source: Maddison (2001)
We
are now once again in a period of deconcentration, an inter-regnum in which a
hegemon is declining. Hegemons perform functions of global governance,
especially by maintaining a level of stability within which the global economy
can operate relatively smoothly. Periods in which there is no hegemon tend to
be more contentious and violent, as contenders for global leadership struggle
with one another over who will be the next hegemon. We contend that the period
in which we are now heading is unlikely to eventuate in the rise of another
hegemon that could replace the
We
will rely primarily on Giovanni Arrighi’s (1994, 2006) careful comparison of
the similarities and differences between the current situation and the systemic
conditions that existed during the decline of British hegemony in the last
decades of the 19th century and the early decades of the 20th
century. The similarities
include:
·
the hegemonies occurred in the context of great waves of economic
globalization (Chase-
Dunn, Kawano and Brewer 2000)
·
the hegemon’s loss of comparative advantage in the manufacturing of
consumer goods and then
capital
goods,
·
the emergence of a period of financialization in which the hegemon’s
centrality in the global
economy
appears to recover, albeit temporarily. The elements of this include:
o the hegemon’s
continuing centrality in global circuits of capital,
o financial advantages
due to control of “world money” (the pound sterling and the U.S. dollar)
o specialization in
financial services, and
o innovation in the
production of new financial securities and forms of investment
These
developments allow the hegemon to experience a late “belle époque” or an
“Indian summer” during which its decline in economic hegemony stabilizes. There
may also be some new technological innovations in this period,[1]
but the main tool for making profits shifts toward the expansion of credit and
financial services.
Another
similarity between the two periods of hegemonic decline is what has been termed
“imperial overreach.” Some of the leaders of the declining hegemon come to fear
that financialization is a bubble that cannot continue to expand, and so they
choose to play the other card in the hegemon’s hand --preponderant military
superiority (Kennedy 1980; Modelski 2005).
The story of the neoconservative plan to restore global order by using
Another
similarity: the language of the declining hegemon is English. This has had a
huge consequence for global linguistic standardization. Great efforts to
promote a synthetic global language, Esperanto, in order to facilitate global
communication and cooperation, failed. But English has become the de facto
language of global business despite that it is resisted and resented by many
national cultures and that cosmopolitans and multiculturalists try to support
multilingual interaction and communication. This has largely been the product
of two centuries of hegemony by English-speaking powers and successive waves of
global economic integration.
But
there are also important differences between the two periods of
hegemonic decline. The British went into
decline during a period in which the world-system was still greatly structured
by colonial empires, including the huge
While
the U.S. internal regime is somewhat similar to that of Great Britain, it is
also different. The biggest differences have to do with size and access to internal
resources. Whereas the British Isles are small, the United States came to be a
continental-sized power with substantial internal natural resources. Britain
became the workshop of a world in which it needed to import a lot of raw
materials, whereas the U.S. has internal raw materials that compete with the
products of other lands (Bonini 2009).
Having
been formed as a republic, and having largely obliterated the Southern landed
aristocracy, the U.S. is a purer form of capitalist democracy than Britain was
or is:
·
No House of Lords;
·
No constitutional monarchy;
·
A more complicated and purely ideological version of citizenship that
was needed to incorporate immigrants from quite different cultural backgrounds;
·
A partially-formed welfare state constituted more around the status
of soldier than the status of citizen (Skocpol 1992);
·
A labor movement that has been militant at times, but in which the
radical elements were more thoroughly defeated and politically marginalized.
The U.S. a purer form of the liberal capitalist
democracy than its mother country was or is.
There are also both
important similarities and important differences between the 19th and
20th century waves of globalization that need to be taken into
account in order to understand the contemporary world historical
situation. Both were periods of
increasing integration based on long-distance trade, increasing foreign
investment and the expansion and cheapening of global transportation and
communications. In both periods markets were deregulated and disembedded from
political and socio-cultural controls (Polanyi 1944). In both waves of
globalization a hegemonic core power rose to centrality in the global political
economy and then declined, losing first its comparative advantages in the production
of consumer goods and then capital goods. Both declining hegemons then used their
centrality in global networks to make money on financial services. Indeed, much
of the whole world economy became financially organized around the hegemon,
whose currency served as world money. The size of the symbolic economy of
“securities” – financial instruments representing ostensible future income
streams—grew far larger than the economy that was based on transactions of
material goods and services. In both waves of globalization capitalist
industrialization spread to new areas and came to involve a far larger number
of the world’s people in global networks of production and exchange.
There
were also important structural differences between the two waves of globalization.
Again, formal colonialism was abolished from the global polity during the most
recent great wave of globalization. The interstate system of legally sovereign
states was extended to the non-core, and so core states could no longer extract
tax revenues from their colonial empires. In the late 19th century
and early 20th century the British were able to use their empire,
especially its direct control over India, to finance the operations of the
British state. And Britain also was able to mobilize large numbers of soldiers
from its colonies to fight in the Boer Wars and in World War I. Both colonial
revenue and cannon fodder were available to the hegemon as well as to some of the
other contending core powers. That is a
source of support that no longer exists because of the evolution of global
governance. When the U.S., like Britain, began to use its centrality in global
military power to try to shore up its declining hegemony, it had to rely
primarily on U.S. citizens to perform soldierly duties. And it could not, as
did the British, directly tax a colonial empire to financially support its
adventures.
Of
course, there have been functional substitutes. The U.S. has tried to get its
allies to pay more of the costs of the Gulf Wars and the war in Afghanistan by
sending troops. Soldiers have been recruited disproportionately from
non-citizen immigrants within the United States by holding out the promise of
gaining formal citizenship. And the U.S. government has increasingly privatized
security by hiring companies of mercenaries to provide services in war zones.
There have been huge efforts to rely on “smart warfare technologies” as a
substitute for troops on the ground. None of these new factors have made the
U.S. foray into “imperial over-reach” any more successful than was the British
effort. The transition from hegemonic leadership to a policy that unilaterally employs
military supremacy in what appears to be a self-serving way generates too much
resistance from both the targets of coercion and from erstwhile allies. The
costs of empire were great in the 19th century, but they went up in
the 20th century because formal legal colonialism had been abolished.
Rather than using colonial subjects as cannon fodder the U.S. must use
immigrants seeking citizenship and highly paid private mercenaries. [2]
The United States: “Too Large To
Fail”
Probably the most
important structural difference between the 19th and 20th
century waves of globalization is the far greater relative size of the hegemon.
Figure 2 shows the proportions that the U.S. and British home markets
constituted in the total world Gross Domestic Product. At its peak in about
1900 Britain’s share was less than 10%. At its peak in 1945 the U.S. share was
35% and, though it has declined in a series of steps down since then, it was still
19% in 2007. This is nearly twice as large as the British economy was at its
peak. Thus the relative size of the hegemon in the larger world economy has
more than doubled. This simple fact has allowed the U.S. to play the
financialization card much more effectively than the British were able to do.
Figure 2 graphs the
shares of global GDP of selected countries: the United States, the United
Kingdom, China, India, Russia/USSR and the 12 European countries that were the
original members of the European Union (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland,
France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Sweden, UK, Portugal, Spain) added
together to show what has happened with the European Union’s trajectory in the
global economy. GDP is a measure of economic size that is strongly influenced
by territorial and population size as well as by level of economic development.
Figure 2 shows the U.S. trajectory that is the main focus of this paper. As
reported in Chase-Dunn, Reifer, Jorgenson and Lio (2005) the U.S. share of the
global economy peaked in 1945 when the rest of the developed world was in a
shambles as result of the destruction caused by World War II. Since then the U.S. share has declined, but
the downward slope has been interrupted by two periods in which the U.S. share
stabilized for a few years. These periods were from 1958 to 1968 and from 1985
to 1997. And there were brief reversals of the downtrend from 1947 to 1951 and
from 1997 to 1999. Since 2000 the U.S. share has steadily declined.
Figure
2: Country shares of world GDP,
1820-2006
Figure
3 is a similar graph that shows the same countries and time period as Figure 2
except that it displays the GDP per capita of each country as a ratio to the
world average GDP per capita. This is more purely a measure of relative
economic development rather than economic size.
Figure 3: GDP Per Capita as a ratio to World Average GDP
Per Capita
The GDP per capita ratios for the European
Union (EU) shown in Figure 3 were computed by summing the population of all EU
members and dividing the EU GDP by this summed total population to
get the average GDP per capita for all EU nations. Then we took this
average GDPPC and divided it by the average world GDP per capita to get the GDP
per capita ratios.
There are important differences between
Figures 2 and 3 as well as some similarities. The U.S. trajectory is similar in
the two graphs until about 1980. After that the relative level of economic
development shown in Figure 3 rose again during the neoliberal financialization
period from 1980 to 2000, whereas in purely size terms shown in Figure 2 the
U.S. trajectory was flat during this period. In both graphs the U.S. declined
sharply after 2000. The trajectory of the EU is also quite different in the two
graphs. In terms of economic size (Figure 2) the EU declined after 1970, while
in terms of relative level of development (Figure 3) the EU went up from 1950
to 1980 and then flattened out and then declined. Japan’s rise was much more
dramatic in terms of relative develop than it was in terms of size. And huge
differences are shown in the relationships that China and India display with
the other core powers. In terms of economic size (and using the PPP exchange
rates provided by Maddison) China seems to have converged with the U.S. by 2007
shown in Figure 2. But in Figure 3 (relative levels of development) China and
India were still far below the U.S and the other core powers.
The British were
capital investors in the rest of the world, and returning profits on foreign
investments were an important factor sustaining the “belle époque” of the
Edwardian era before World War I. The U.S. has obtained great returns on
investment abroad, but it has also been sustained by huge flows of investment
from abroad into the U.S. This is a big difference between British and U.S.
hegemonic decline. The British mainly exported capital and got returns from investments
abroad. The U.S. has done that too. The investments abroad of U.S.
multinational corporations grew rapidly in the decades after World War II. U.S.
companies established subsidiaries in many countries, branch offices and
manufacturing operations as well as resource-extracting firms (mines, logging
companies, fruit companies, etc). This is called “direct” investment because
the headquarters firm owns and controls the subsidiary. Other core countries and some non-core
countries also greatly expanded the operations of their own multinational
corporations. The core countries also expanded their purchases of bonds from
foreign national and local governments, and eventually core capital flowed in
to newly emerging stock markets in noncore countries. This is called
“portfolio” investment because the owner does not have control over the
day-to-day operations of the entities whose securities are purchased. All this
was similar to the export of capital by the British and other core countries in
the great wave of 19th century globalization.
But then something
different emerged -- huge inflows of foreign investment into the United States,
first from other core countries, especially Japan and Britain, but later from
non-core countries as well, especially China. It is these flows, which have
taken the form of buying bonds as well as investment in real estate and stocks,
which sustained the long U.S. expansion during the 1990s and the first years of
the 21st century. Michael Mann (2006) has called this “dollar
seignorage.” U.S. federal government
spending has been made possible without increasing taxes because governments
and investors abroad have been willing to buy U.S. government bonds. This
massive influx of money has also allowed the U.S. to sustain a huge trade deficit
in which imports of foreign goods and services have come to vastly exceed the
amount of U.S. goods that are exported, despite the outsourcing of jobs by U.S.
companies (see Figure 4). Because of its ability to sell bonds the U.S.
government was able to keep interest rates low and so developers built new
housing, and homeowners were able to sell their old houses and move into larger
houses because the prices of housing tended to go up. Residential mortgages
were also subsidized as they had been since the G.I Bill of Rights after World
War II, but the mortgage industry kept expanding credit and lowering the
requirements for obtaining a housing loan. Mortgages from the residential and
commercial real estate markets were also repackaged by Wall Street financial
entrepreneurs as global commodities and sold to institutional investors all
over the world. Thus did the wave of financialization during the U.S. hegemonic
decline take on new dimensions that differentiate it from what happened at the
end of the 19th century. The
U.S. government was also able to finance overseas wars in Afghanistan and Iraq
by selling bonds to foreign investors, including the Chinese, who came to have
such a stake in the U.S.-led financial bubble that they have become important
supporters rather than challengers.
Figure 4: U.S Trade Balance
(Exports/Imports), 1970-2006
The dollar sector of
the world economy is so large that there are no alternatives big enough to
replace it even when foreign investors have become disenchanted about the
prospects of future returns on their investments. The Euro would seem a
possibility, but the sheer size of the mountain of securities in
dollar-denominated investments makes the Euro sector look like a dwarf. The
difference in relative size between Britain in the 19th century and
the U.S. in the 20th century means that the rest of the world is
much more dependent on the economy of the hegemon now, and would-be competitors
have come to have a huge stake in the ability of the U.S. to buy their
products. As is sometimes said about gigantic corporations such as General
Motors, the U.S. economy is “too large to fail.”
The Global Policeman
The U.S. is also far
more supreme in military terms than Britain ever was. The United States
currently maintains 737 military bases abroad. By comparison, at the peak of
its global power in 1898 Britain had 36 bases (Johnson 2006: 138-39).
Figure 5: Seapower:
Warships as a Proportion of Total Warships
Modelski and
Thompson (1988; 1996) contend that global reach, as indicated by naval power,
is the best measure of concentration and deconcentration of power in the global
system. Their careful study of the evolution of warships has been used to
construct a measure of the rise and fall of global military power. Figure 5 shows
the relative seapower of Britain, the U.S., France, Russia and Germany since
1820. Modelski and Thompson (1988:11-13) estimate naval power by obtaining
information on the number of warships in the possession of each great power and
then dividing this figure by the total number of warships in the possession of
all world naval powers. This index for
each nation represents the national share of the world’s warships. Modelski and
Thompson (1988:44) only include “global powers” in their calculation of the seapower
index, which they define as nations that either (1) possess at least 10% of all
warships in the world or (2) account for at least 5% of total world naval
expenditures. Utilizing these criteria,
while multiple nation-states are considered global powers for years prior to
World War II, only the US and Russia qualify as world powers after World War II.
Figure 5 shows the
declining relative seapower of Great Britain, the amazingly low relative
seapower of Germany, the main challenger for hegemony in World Wars I and II,
and the relationship between the U.S. and the Soviet Union during the Cold War.
The overwhelming superiority of the U.S. has gotten even greater since the fall
of the Soviet Union in 1989.
Another measure of
relative military power is that developed by the Correlates of War Project
(Singer 1987). The Correlates of War (COW) Project estimates the power of
nation-states by selecting key indicators that reflect the breadth and depth of
the resources a nation could utilize in militarized disputes. This is referred to as national material
capabilities (NMC). NMC is measured by utilizing national estimates of
demographic, industrial, and military capacity to create on overall measure of
NMC, these variables are: total population, urban population, primary energy
consumption, iron and steel production, military personnel and military
expenditures.
Figure 6 graphs the
COW NMC values for the U.S., Great Britain, the European Union, China and
India. There are some very big
differences from the seapower graph presented in Figure 5. The COW measure takes into account the size
of the military as indicated by the number of soldiers. The Chinese military is
very large because the Chinese population is very large. Demographic size has always been an important
component of war capability. The
Modelski and Thompson emphasis on seapower and global reach distinguishes
between regional power systems in which forces confront their adjacent
neighbors (usually with armed ground forces), and global power, in which the
ability to coordinate force on an intercontinental scale using naval power is
important (see also Rasler and Thompson 1984). They see an important
interaction between global and regional military geopolitics that can only be
observed and analyzed by distinguishing between naval global reach and regional
army power. The results shown in the Correlates of War NMC graph (Figure 6)
conflate the global reach (naval) and regional (army) power estimates. Figure 6 implies that China surpassed the
U.S. in terms of relative military capability in 1995. This only makes sense by
making the kind of global/regional distinction proposed by Modelski and
Thompson.
Figure 6: Correlates of War (COW) National Military Capability (NMC) as a Proportion of Total World Military Capability
We concur with
Modelski, Thompson and Rasler that there is an important distinction between
military global reach and the ability to exercise military power vis a vis
adjacent states. But for us this is conflated with the link between global
capitalism and global military power. The kind of global capitalism represented
by the U.S. and British hegemonies has been liberal and neoliberal capitalism
in which capitalist merchants, industrialists and financiers have unusually
predominant sway over the policies of their national states. But the U.S. is
also unusual in the extent to which it is both a continental-sized state with
important internal natural resources and a state that is under the control of
global capitalists. We also agree, at
least partially, with some of the theorists of a new stage of global capitalism
who are focusing attention on the notion of global class relations and the
emergence of a transnational state. The trajectory of the U.S discussed here is
part of the long process of the transnationalization of class relations and a
process of political globalization in which international political
organizations have become more and more important for global governance.
The strongest
economic challenges to U.S. hegemony in manufacturing during the decades after
World War II came from Germany and Japan, the countries that lost the war. During the long Cold War between the U.S. and
the Soviet Union, the other core countries were content to let the U.S. be the
superpower in military terms and so they did not develop their own military
capabilities to any significant extent. After World War II both Germany and
Japan renounced the use of military power, and kept only small capabilities,
relying on the U.S. for protection. The consequence, after the demise of the
Soviet Union, is that serious global military power is a near monopoly of the
hegemon. This is a very stable military structure compared with what existed in
the world-system before World War I. No single country, and not even a
coalition of countries, could militarily challenge the United States. But this
structure had been legitimized by the Cold War and by a relatively multilateral
approach to policy decisions employed by the United States in which major
decisions were taken in consultation with the other core powers.
The Democratic Peace and Future
Rivalry
International
relations theorists have argued that conflict within the core is quite unlikely
because all the major core powers have democratic regimes. The “democratic
peace” idea is that sharing a set of political values makes conflict less
likely, and that democratic regimes should be less likely than non-democratic
ones to initiate warfare. The relevance of this hypothesis for the future of
the probability of war among powerful states is based on the assumption that
the great powers remain democratic. This seems plausible enough if we could
assume stable economic development, well-legitimized institutions of global
governance and fair access to a growing supply of natural resources. Environmental
crises, population pressure, financial crises and hegemonic decline might well
provide challenges that the “democratic peace” factor is not strong enough to
mitigate (Chase-Dunn and Podobnik 1995).
A similar argument
applies in the case of those who contend that a global stage of capitalism has
emerged ,or is emerging, in which there is a single integrated transnational
capitalist class (Sklair 2001) and an emerging transnational state (Robinson
2004, 2008). Globalization has indeed increased the degree of global
coordination and integration, but will the institutions that have emerged be
strong enough to prevent the return of conflict among the great powers during a
new period of deglobalization, hegemonic decline, peak oil, resource wars and
strong challenges from social movements and counter-hegemonic regimes in the
non-core? That is the question.
The United States
has been in decline in terms of hegemony in economic production since at least
the 1970s and, as we have seen above, this has been similar in many respects to
the decline of British hegemony in the late 19th century. The great
post-World War II wave of globalization and financialization is faltering, and
some analysts predict another descent into deglobalization. The declining
economic and political hegemony of the U.S. poses huge challenges for global
governance. Newly emergent national economies such as India and China need to
be fitted in to the global structure of power. The unilateral use of military
force by the declining hegemon has further delegitimated the institutions of
global governance and has provoked resistance and challenges. A similar bout of
“imperial over-reach” in the late 19th and early 20th
centuries on the part of Britain led to a period of hegemonic rivalry and world
war. Such an outcome is less likely now, but not impossible.
After the attacks of
September 11, 2001 the United States adopted a more unilateral approach in
which actions were taken despite the opposition of some of its most powerful
allies. Germany and the U.N. Security Council did not support the invasion of
Iraq in 2003. This unilateral approach was reminiscent of Britain’s “imperial
over-reach” at the turn of the 20th century, but the context is importantly different.
In both cases uneven economic development has led to the emergence of new
challenges to the economic pre-eminence of the hegemon, but during the U.S.
hegemonic decline there are no serious military challengers among the
contending states. Armed resistance is mainly confined to those who employ
“weapons of the weak” (e.g. suicide bombers) and a few low-intensity guerrilla
forces in non-core countries. The U.S.
has been encouraging Germany and Japan to expand their military capabilities in
order to take up some of the expensive burden of policing the world. The U.S.
share of total global military power is so great that it is hard to imagine a
situation any time soon in which the structure of military power among core
states would become similar to the more even balance of miltary capabilities
that existed before World War I.
The U.S. would have
to greatly reduce its military capability, and potential challengers would have
to dramatically increase theirs. Since military capability is highly dependent
on economic wealth, the decline of U.S. economic hegemony could eventually have
such a result, a point that was made by Barack Obama during the presidential
campaign of 2008. But it takes time to build up military capability. This could happen quickly if an arms race
situation were to emerge such as the one that existed before World War I
between Germany and Britain. But in the current situation who would play the
role that Germany played before World War I -- an economic challenger that
morphs into a military challenger? No single country could do this because the
U.S. supremacy is so great. But a coalition of countries (Japan and China,
China and Russia, Germany and Russia, or the European Union) could conceivably
do it at some point in the future.
Another Round of U. S. Hegemony?
Modelski
and Thompson (1994) contended that there were two rounds of British hegemony;
one in the 18th century and another one in 19th century.
They contend that under some circumstances a hegemon can succeed itself. The
logic of sclerosis can be overcome if new internal interest groups who are
partisans of new industries can overcome the power of the vested interests of
the old industries. Normally this is not possible within the confines of a
single national polity and this explains why hegemony usually moves on. Indeed
uneven develop has been the main rule for centuries. If this were not so an
initial comparative advantage would last for millennia. Mesopotamia, the
original heartland of cities and states in the Bronze Age, would still be the
leading edge of human sociocultural evolution. Long term studies of the
largest of cities and empires show that hegemonic empires rarely succeed
themselves, although this has happened occasionally (Wilkinson 1991).
The most explicit argument for the likelihood of another round of U.S. hegemony was made by Joachim Rennstich (2001, 2004). Rennstich noted that the decline of earlier great powers had much to do with institutional rigidities. The British had a hard time moving from the family-centered firm to the corporate structure pioneered in the U.S. But the U.S. is a more flexible society with a history of political efforts to restrain monopolies. The rise of the NASDAQ stock exchange despite resistance from the New York Stock Exchange is an important example of U.S. institutional flexibility. Rennstich contended that the U.S. has developed a powerful capability by which newly rising industries could escape the clutches of old vested interests and flourish. He noted that high technology firms that felt that they were being sidelined at the New York Stock Exchange were able to form their own stock market, the NASDAQ. This was possible because the culture of the U.S. genuinely supports innovation and independence, and because an anti-monopoly tradition in the U.S. federal government occasionally gets trotted out by political entrepreneurs who go after firms that appear to be too greedy at the expense of the consuming public.
Rennstich also noted that U.S. culture is somewhat unusually open to social and
economic change relative to other national cultures. Europeans worry about
genetically modified foods (GMOs), whereas consumers in the U.S. do not seem to
mind that ‘frankenfoods” can be sold to them without labeling. Rennstich’s
point is that this is a very flexible culture that is open to change, and that
this characteristic is probably an advantage in future competition over new
lead industries (especially biotechnology). Of course there are other
interpretations of the GMO issue. Large corporations have great influence over
the activities of government regulators in the U.S. and spend large amounts of
money to influence public opinion. These
factors might work for or against a new round of hegemony based on
reindustrialization depending on the balance of forces within the U.S.
corporate elite. Arguably the powers
that be on Wall Street do not need another round of U.S. hegemony based on new
lead industries because they are making plenty of profits by investing outside
of the U.S.. This is similar to what happened with the expansion of foreign
investment by the British capitalist class.
It is well-known that the U.S. has had a comparative advantage in higher
education, especially in research universities that develop advances in both
pure and applied sciences. This advantage should lead to an advantage in the
commercialization of new technological advances and, in principal, could be the
basis of a restoration of U.S. economic hegemony that is profitable enough to
continue to support those aspects of hegemony that are less profitable.
Information technology has probably already run the course of the product cycle
from technological rents to competition over production costs.
There will undoubtedly be a few new gadgets and profitable Internet services that will redound to U.S. firms such as Apple and Google, but this is not likely to be the basis of a new growth industry in which returns are concentrated within the U.S. We have already mentioned that British hegemonic decline occurred despite that Britain continued to lead in some new high technologies such radio, radar and television. Britain also maintained its centrality in the global telegraph network during World War I, enabling it to read communications between the Germans and other countries that were intended to be secret (Hugill 1999). But a few cutting edge innovations are not enough for the restoration of economic hegemony.
Biotechnology and nanotechnology have greater possibilities. And green technology that allows more efficient use of natural resources is also a possibility. A restoration of U.S. economic hegemony could also provide the resources for a potential restoration of U.S. political hegemony. Of course the new regime would have to distance itself from the kind of unilateral adventurism displayed in the second Iraq war, and would have to respect the existing institutions of multilateral global governance that the U.S. championed after World War II. Greater concern about global equality and a genuine effort to understand peoples who are culturally different might go a long way toward undoing the damage done by the neoconservatives during the Bush administration from 2000 to 2008.
One advantage of such a development that might find support both at home and
abroad is that the current unipolar structure of the global military apparatus
could be maintained, thus reducing the probability that another round of
hegemonic rivalry might descend into world war, as it always has in the past.
Such a unipolar structure of military power could be made much more legitimate
by bringing it under the auspices of the United Nations or an expanded and
democratized North Atlantic Treaty Organization. If this were combined with
disarmament of national forces, the overall size and expense of the global
military apparatus could be reduced.
Rennstich made his
argument about the possibility of another round of U.S. hegemony ten years ago. The characteristics he pointed out may have
partly accounted for the recovery of the U.S. in the 1990s, though these
characteristics will probably not be strong enough to overcome the path
dependencies that stand in the way of a geneuine resportation of U.S. hegemony
based on comparative advantage in production.
The Obama campaign
in 2006 promised a new political regime with a strong industrial policy of
renewal that was willing to husband resources and invest in education and
product development, and that could overcome the internal resistance to new
taxes by mobilizing a popular constituency to support these developmental
projects. The election of Obama reminded world-systems evolutionists that world
history is open ended. The demise of these policy proposals also reminds us
that unexpected conjunctural events tend to get ironed out by the structural
forces of the longue duree.
The most recent
financial meltdown that began in 2006 is similar in many ways with earlier debt
cycles, but different in others (Chase-Dunn and Kwon 2010). Despite
greater reliance on less centrally-coordinated market-based approaches to debt
problems (Suter 2009), there has not been a total collapse of the global
financial system. The Wall Street bail-out allowed the stock markets to
recover. There appears to be a very slow recovery of investment but a
continuing high level of unemployment. This said, the global economy has not
really collapsed. There have been a few protectionist challenges to the
“free trade” regime, but trade globalization was still going up as recently as
2006. Investment globalization has become wobbly, but it has not yet
collapsed. The recent meltdown has not as yet led to something like the
Great Depression that began in 1929. Within the United States there has
not been a rebirth of strong anti-capitalist social movements. Rather the
populist right has made the most hay out of anti-Wall Street sentiment. A “New
Deal” situation has not emerged. Rather the right has gained support by
accusing the black President of being a socialist and a Muslim, while those on
the Left him as a Hoover rather than a Roosevelt. All this portends a
continuing slow decline of U.S. hegemony rather than any abrupt change or
another round of hegemony by the U.S. This is not surprising from the point of
view of recurrent cycles of hegemonic rise and fall.
Rivalry, Ecocatastrophe and
Deglobalization: The Perfect Storm
A more likely
scenario for the next several decades is continued U.S. hegemonic decline and
resultant economic and political/military restructuring of the world-system.
Here the scenario bears a strong likeness to what happened during the decline
of British hegemony at the end of the 19th century, but with a few
important differences. We have already seen some developments that are strongly
reminiscent of the British hegemonic decline. The neoliberal “globalization
project” was mainly a crisis-management response to a profit squeeze in manufacturing
when Japan and Germany caught up with the U.S. after recovering from World War
II. The rise of the neoconservatives and unilateral “imperial over-reach” was
again crisis management in response to the obviously untenable position of the
U.S. balance of trade that emerged after 1990. These and the rise of new
economic competitors such as China and India are strong similarities to the
earlier period of hegemonic decline. We have also mentioned the expansion
of finance capital that was an important characteristic of the last phase of
both British hegemony and of U.S. hegemony.
There is
another important difference between the periods of British and U.S.; hegemonic
decline that we have not yet mentioned. British decline and the inter-regnum
between the British and U.S. hegemonies occurred during a period of transition
from the coal to the oil energy regime in which the cost of energy was falling
(Podobnik 2006). This time around hegemony is declining during a period
of generally rising costs of non-renewable resources. This energy cost
difference probably slants the system toward chaos.
It is well-known
that the rise of greater centralization and state-formation over the long run of
sociocultural evolution has been made possible by the ability of complex societies
to capture free energy. Hierarchies and greater complexity are expensive in
energy terms. Reductions in the availability of free energy have often been
associated with the collapse of hierarchies and of complex divisions of labor
(Tainter 1988). The coming peaks of resource production probably also raise the
probability of future resource wars, especially in the absence of a strong and
legitimate hegemon or a legitimate global state (Heinberg 2004).
The size difference
between Britain and the U.S. noted above probably slants against a fast
collapse. Even the economic challengers have a vested interested in the current
U.S.-centered financial system and are unlikely to do intentionally do anything
that will undermine it. They own too many U.S. bonds and they depend too much
on the ability of buyers in the U.S. to purchase their products.
And though
U.S. military capability will undoubtedly decline as the ability of the U.S.
economy to support it wanes, this could take a long time, just as it will take
time for new economic centers to develop their military capabilities. The
military and economic size factors do not preclude hegemonic decline, but they
do slow it down and also put off the onset of strong hegemonic rivalries.
Future environmental
catastrophes are likely due to industrialization and population growth
overshoots and overconsumption in the core. Perhaps global warming could be
slowed down by reducing the production of greenhouse gases. With the election
of Barack Obama the U.S. administration signaled strong support, but the
challenges of global adoption and enforcement seem less likely to be met now.
The pressure to use more coal as oil prices continue to rise is likely to overcome
the all the good intentions and international treaties. Environmental
catastrophe will destabilize both the economy and existing political
arrangements. Fragile states will be challenged by internal resource wars (such
as the “blood diamond” wars in Africa) and whole countries will be increasingly
tempted to use armed force to protect or gain access to natural resources. The
collapse of fisheries, the arrival of peak water, deforestation, and pollution
of the streams, ground water and seas and increasing global temperature and sea
level will add to economic problems and exacerbate population pressures. The
environmental dimension of the current situation could conceivably make a
positive contribution to global governance if the response encourages the
formation of international institutions that can organize a cooperative
approach to solving the problems. But they could also make such a solution less
likely by increasing competition over increasingly scarce natural resources. In
the collapse scenario competition and conflict overwhelm cooperation and
institution-building.
Deglobalization will
mean less international trade, less international investment and the
reemergence of greater local and national self-reliance for the production of
goods and services. The rise of transportation costs because of rising
energy prices is one factor that should reduce international trade. Efforts to
reduce carbon emissions will also involve greater regulation of long distance
transportation by air, ship and truck and this will encourage a return to more
local and regional circuits of production and consumption. International
investment will decline if there is greater international conflict because the
risks associated with investments in distant locations will increase.
Greater local
self-reliance will be good for manufacturing and for farmers in places where
imports have been driving locals out of business. But the cost of many goods
will go up. Services may continue to be supplied internationally if the global
communications grid is maintained. It is expensive to maintain the
satellites and cables, but this may be a good investment because long-distance
communication can increasingly substitute for long-distance transportation.
International business and political meetings can be held in cyberspace rather
than by flying people from continent to continent. The carbon footprint of
transoceanic communication is considerably smaller than the carbon footprint of
transportation because information is lighter than people and goods. But
the infrastructure of global communication also relies on international
cooperation, and so the rise of conflict might make communications less
reliable or the big grid might even come down (Kuecker 2007).
A Global Democratic and Sustainable
Commonwealth?
Eventually the
human species will probably escape from the spiral of population pressure and
ecological degradation that has driven human socio-cultural evolution since the
Stone Age. If the demographic transition continues its march through the Global
South this is likely to occur by the year 2100 or so. After the total human
population ceases to rise it will still take time to become adjusted to the
economic, environmental and political problems that will result from a global
population of 8, 10 or 12 million people. And even then history will not end
because human institutional structures will continue to evolve and to generate
new challenges.
But the focus of
this paper is the next several decades. The problem raised by the analysis
above is that the existing institutions of global governance are in crisis and
a new structure that is both legitimate and capable needs to emerge to enable
the humans to deal with the problems that we have created for ourselves. But
what could speed global state formation up such that an effective and
democratic global government could be formed by the middle of the 21st
century?
First recall that in
our understanding of the evolution of global governance world state formation
has been occurring since the end of the Napoleonic Wars in 1815. The Concert of
Europe was a multilateral international organization with explicit political
intent – the prevention of future revolutions of the type that emerged in
France in 1789 and the prevention of future Napoleonic projects. The Concert of
Europe was fragile and eventually foundered on the differences between the
rigid conservatism of the Austro-Hungarian Empire led by Prince Metternich, and
the somewhat more enlightened conservatism of the British, led by Lord
Castlereigh. But the emergence of a proto-world state was tried again in the
guise of the League of Nations and once again as the United Nations
Organization. We can notice that the big efforts have followed world wars. And
we should also mention that the United Nations is a very long way from being a
true world state in the Weberian sense of a monopoly of legitimate violence.
All the previous
advances in global state formation have taken place after a hegemon has
declined and challengers have been defeated in a world war among hegemonic
rivals. In Warren Wagar’s (1999) future scenario a global socialist state is
able to emerge only after a huge war among core states in which two thirds of
the world’s population are killed. A similar scenario is also suggested by
Heikki Patomäki (2008). The idea here is that major organizational changes
emerge after huge catastrophes when the existing global governance institutions
are in disarray and need to be rebuilt. But using a global war as a deus ex
machina in a science fiction novel is quite different from planning
and implementing a real strategy that relies on a huge disaster in order to
bring about change – “disaster socialism,” to borrow a phrase suggested by
Naomi Klein’s (2007) discussion of how neoliberal globalizers have been able to
make hay out of tragedies. Obviously political actors who seek to promote the
emergence of an effective and democratic global state must also do all that
they can to try to prevent another war among the great powers. Humanistic
morality must trump the possibility of strategic advantage.
This said, it is
very likely that major calamities will occur in the coming decades regardless
of the efforts of far-sighted citizens and social movements. That is why we
have imagined the collapse scenario above. And it would make both tactical and
strategic sense to have plans for how to move forward if indeed a perfect storm
of calamities were to come about.
But we should also
try to imagine how an effective and democratic global government might emerge
in the absence of a huge calamity. Instead we will suppose that a series of
moderate-sized ecological, economic and political calamities that are somewhat
spaced out in time can suffice to provide sufficient disruption of the existing
world order and motivation for its reconstruction along more cooperative,
effective and democratic lines.
The scenario we have
in mind involves a network of alliances among progressive social movements and
political regimes of countries in the Global South along with some allies in
the Global North. We are especially sanguine about the possibility of
relatively powerful semiperipheral states coming to be controlled by democratic
socialist regimes that can provide resources to progressive global parties and
movements. The long-term pattern of semiperipheral development that has
operated in the socio-cultural evolution of world-systems at least since the
rise of paramount chiefdoms suggests that the “advantages of backwardness” may
again play an important role in the coming world revolution.
Our scenario would
involve a coalescent party-network of the New Global Left that would emerge
from the existing “movement of movements” participating in the World Social
Forum (WSF) process. The first WSF was mainly organized by the Brazilian labor and
landless peasant movements. The global meetings have been held in the Global
South (Brazil, India, Kenya and Senegal).
The long evolution
of the modern world-system has been marked by waves of increasing democracy and
global state formation brought about by a series of world revolutions and
efforts by pragmatic conservatives to construct hegemony based on both coercion
and consent. The form that will best suited for the future is a global
democratic and collectively rational commonwealth. The main source of this
sweeping change is already emerging in the contemporary semiperiphery and the
periphery. The most powerful challenges
to capitalism in the 20th century came from semiperipheral Russia and China,
and the strongest supporters of the contemporary global justice movement are
semiperipheral countries such as Brazil, Mexico and Venezuela and South Africa.
Popular social movements have become increasingly transnational and information
technology makes it much easier to organize global party networks than when
Lenin tried to use a radio transmitter to call activists to the meeting of the
first Comintern. And different forms of capitalism are challenging the
neoliberal form championed by Britain and the United States. Semiperipheral
societies are not constrained to the same degree as older core societies. They
are freer to devise and implement new institutions. China’s “market society” is
a different form of capitalism. Giovanni Arrighi (2006) contended that the
Chinese form may be more capable of dealing effectively with the challenges of
“globalization from below” than the neoliberal form has been. The historically
transformative role of the semiperiphery has been strong in the past and is likely
to be strong in the future.
Bibliography
Arrighi, Giovanni 1994 The Long Twentieth
Century. London: Verso.
Arrighi, Giovanni and Beverly Silver 1999 Chaos
and Governance in the Modern World-System: Comparing
Hegemonic
Transitions. Minneapolis:
University ofMinnesota Press.
______________
2006 Adam Smith in Beijing. London: Verso
Chase-Dunn, Christopher and Bruce Podobnik 1995 "The next world war: world-system cycles and trends," Journal of World-Systems Research 1:6
Chase-Dunn, C. Yukio Kawano and Benjamin Brewer
2000 “Trade globalization since 1795:
waves of integration in the world-system” American Sociological Review 65,1:77-95
Chase-Dunn, C. Thomas Reifer, Andrew Jorgenson
and Shoon Lio 2005
"The U.S. Trajectory: A Quantitative
Reflection, Sociological Perspectives 48,2: 233-254.
Chase-Dunn, C. and Kirk Lawrence 2010 “ The Next
Three Futures: Another U.S. Hegemony,
Global Collapse or Global Democracy?” Global Society. https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows47/irows47.htm
Chase-Dunn, C. and R.E. Niemeyer 2009 “The world revolution of 20xx” in Mathias Albert,
Gesa Bluhm, Han Helmig, Andreas Leutzsch, Jochen Walter (eds.) Transnational Political Spaces.
Campus Verlag: Frankfurt/New York
Chase-Dunn, Christopher and Hiroko Inoue 2010 “Accelerating Global State Formation
and Democracy” IROWS Working Paper #55
Chase-Dunn C. and Roy Kwon 2010 “Crises and
Counter-Movements in World Evolutionary
Perspective” IROWS Working Paper #60 https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows60/irows60.htm
Bonini, Astra 2009 “Is
there Really a ‘Resource Curse’?: Raw Material Wealth and Economic Mobility in
the World System”
Presented at the Annual Meetings of the
American Sociological
Association.
Brenner, Robert 2002 The Boom and the Bubble:
The U.S. in the World Economy. London: Verso.
Bunker, Stephen and Paul Ciccantell 2005 Globalization
and the Race for Resources. Baltimore:
Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Carroll, William K. 2010 The Making of a
Transnational Capitalist Class. London: Zed Press.
Friedman, Jonathan and Christopher
Chase-Dunn (eds.) 2005. Hegemonic
Declines: Present and
Past. Boulder, CO.: Paradigm Press.
Go, Julian 2007 “Global fields and
imperial forms: field theory and the British and American
empires” Paper presented at the annual meeting
of the American Sociological Association, New York.
Goldfrank, Walter L. 1999
“Beyond hegemony” in Volker Bornschier and Christopher Chase-Dunn
(eds.) The Future of Global Conflict. London:
Sage.
Heinberg, Richard. 2004. Powerdown.
Gabriola Island, BC: Island Press.
Hugill, Peter J. 1999 Global
Communications since 1844: Geopolitics and Technology. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Johnson, Chalmers A.
2006. Nemesis : the last days of the American Republic.
New York: Metropolitan Books.
Kennedy, Paul 1987 The Rise and Fall of the
Great Powers, New York: Vintage Books.
Klein, Naomi.
2007. The Shock Doctrine: The Rise of Disaster Capitalism. New York: Henry Holt and
Company.
Kuecker, Glen 2007 “The perfect storm” International
Journal of Environmental, Cultural and Social
Sustainability 3
Lawrence, Kirk. 2009 “Toward a democratic and
collectively rational global commonwealth:
semiperipheral
transformation in a post-peak world-system” in Phoebe Moore and Owen
Worth, Globalization and the Semiperiphery: New York:Palgrave MacMillan.
Lachmann, Richard 2003 “Elite Self-Interest and Economic Decline in Early Modern Europe
American Sociological Review 68, 3: 346-372
McCormick, Thomas J. 1989 America’s Half Century: United States Foreign Policy in the Cold War.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Maddison, Angus.
2001. The World Economy: A
Millennial Perspective. Paris:
Organization of
Economic Cooperation and
Development.
Mann, Michael. 2002. Incoherent
Empire. New
York, NY: Verso.
_____________ 2006 “The Recent Intensification
of American Economic and Military Imperialism:
Are They Connected? Presented at the annual
meeting of the American Sociological
Association, Montreal, August 11.
Patomaki, Heikki 2008 The Political Economy
of Global Security. New York: Routledge.
Podobnik, Bruce 2006 Global Energy Shifts.
Philadelphia, PA: Temple University Press
Quigley, Carroll.
1981 The Anglo-American Establishment. New York: Books in Focus
Rasler, Karen and William R. Thompson 1994 The Great Powers and Global Struggle, 1490-
1990. Lexington: University of Kentucky Press.
Reifer, Thomas E. 2009-10 “Lawyers, Guns and Money: Wall Street
Lawyers, Investment Bankers and
Global Financial Crises, Late 19th to Early 21st Century” Nexus: Chapman's
Journal of Law
& Policy, 15: 119-133
Rennstich, Joachim K. 2001 “The Future of Great
Power Rivalries.” In Wilma Dunaway (ed.) New
Theoretical Directions for the
21st Century World-System New York: Greenwood Press.
_______ 2002 “The
phoenix cycle:global leadership transition in a long-wave
perspective.” Paper
presented
at the annual spring Political Economy of World-Systems conference,
University of California, Riverside, May 3-4.
Robinson, William I. 2004 A Theory of Global
Capitalism. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University
Press
_______________
2008. Latin American and Global Capitalism: A Critical Globalization
Perspective.
Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins University Press.
Santos, Boaventura de Sousa 2006 The Rise of
the Global Left. London: Zed Press.
Singer, J. David. (1987).
"Reconstructing the Correlates of War Dataset on Material Capabilities of
States,
1816-1985" International Interactions, 14: 115-32.
Sklair, Leslie 2001 The Transnational
Capitalist Class. Malden, MA: Blackwell.
Skocpol, Theda 1992 Protecting
soldiers and mothers : the political origins of social policy in the United
States
Cambridge, Mass. :
Belknap Press of Harvard University Press
Silver,
Beverly and E. Slater 1999. “The Social Origins of World Hegemonies”. In G.
Arrighi, et al
.
Chaos and Governance in the Modern World System. Minneapolis: University
of Minnesota Press, 151-216.
Stokes, Doug and Sam Raphael 2010 Global Energy
Security and American Hegemony Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press
Suter,
Christian 1992
Debt cycles in the world-economy : foreign loans, financial crises, and debt
settlements, 1820-1990 Boulder : Westview Press
_____________2009 “Financial crises and the
institutional evolution of the global debt restructuring regime,
1820-2008” Presented at the PEWS Conference on
“The Social and Natural Limits of Globalization and the Current Conjuncture”
Tainter, Joseph A. 1988. The Collapse of
Complex Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Taylor, Peter 1996 The Way the Modern
World Works: Global Hegemony to Global Impasse. New
York:
Wiley.
Wagar, W. Warren. 1999. A Short History of
the Future, 3rd ed. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago
Press.
Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1984a “The three
instances of hegemony in the history of the capitalist
world-economy.” Pp. 100-108 in Gerhard
Lenski (ed.) Current Issues and Research in Macrosociology,
International Studies in Sociology and Social
Anthropology, Vol. 37. Leiden: E.J. Brill.
Wilkinson, David.1991 “Core, peripheries and
civilizations,” Pp. 113-166 in C. Chase-Dunn and T.D. Hall (eds.)
Core/Periphery
Relations in Precapitalist Worlds.
http://www.irows.ucr.edu/cd/books/c-p/chap4.htm