From Contract Manufacture to Global Player:
Is China Moving to the Global Core?
Andrea
Komlosy
University of Vienna, Department
for Social and Economic History
Associate Professor
Harvard University,
Weatherhead Center for
International Relations
An earlier version
was presented at the ENIUGH conference, Paris 2014, This is IROWS Working Paper
#94 available at https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows94/irows94.htm draft v. 4-29-15 please do not quote or cite
without permission, 12963 words
< komlosy@wcfia.harvard.edu>
Abstract
This contribution departs from a field study carried
out in the Shanghai region textile companies, coping with the Chinese governments plans since 2006 to upgrade the economic
structure, allowing China to overcome the peripheral status of low end
manufacture, move on towards a consumer society and become a leading centre of
the world economy. The companies’ strategies vary broadly between prolonging
the low skill–low wage model of contract manufacture, moving up the
commodity-chain by introducing design, branding and new product lines, and
taking over of command functions, going along with the outsourcing of low skill
tasks into the Chinese interior and abroad. The empirical study serves to
highlight the contradictions of the Chinese path of modernization and adds
evidence to the more general debate about China’s future.
Size, cultural heritage, labour regime, work ethics
and political system are among the factors to explain, how dependency can be
transformed into the position of a global competitor, taking over control over
global communication and production lines. The outcome is far from sure yet,
however, and the study confirms sceptical voices doubting China’s rise to a new
global core. The contribution also asks for the consequences of a possible
success. Catching up in the world economy, goes hand in hand with social and
regional polarization within the country, as well as with a new international
dominance. Neighbours turn into outsourcing locations and suppliers of raw
materials, international relations help to secure commodity flows; China starts
to demonstrate military presence. In the case of China, economic core formation
is inseparably linked to the question of global hegemony. Does the rise of a
new core, promoting new alliances in the Global South, represent the emergence
of a multi-polar world? Or will we rather face a hegemonic shift, China aiming
to take over US-hegemony?
After
declaring “Reform and Opening” in 1978, the Chinese export-economy entered the
global commodity chains fulfilling low skill and low cost contract
manufacturing for global buyers. This contribution asks for the specific
conditions allowing China to overcome the peripheral status of low end
manufacture and become a leading centre of the world economy. Size, cultural
heritage, labour regime, work ethics and political system are among the factors
to explain, why and how dependency could be transformed into the position of a
global competitor, taking over control over global communication and production
lines. The contribution also asks for the consequences of the success story.
Catching up in the world economy, goes hand in hand with social and regional
polarization within the country, as well as with a new international dominance.
Neighbours turn into outsourcing locations and suppliers of raw materials,
international relations help to secure commodity flows; China starts to
demonstrate military presence. In the case of China, economic core formation is
inseparably linked to the question of global hegemony. Does the rise of a new
core, promoting new alliances in the Global South, represent the emergence of a
multi-polar world? Or will we rather face a hegemonic shift, China aiming to
take over US-hegemony?
The
Chinese case offers a good occasion to re-evaluate core and periphery as
analytical tools. It shows that the categories undergo permanent change and
re-definition; that history, size, political power and cultural features are as
decisive for economic performance as economic ones. And that changing positions
of one great power in the world economy, do have consequences on intra and
inter state relations, rendering core and periphery relational, entangled
categories.
“Does the
21st Century Belong to China”? This was the title of a public debate
in Toronto on June 17, 2011, also known as the Munk
Debate. Niall Ferguson, history professor at Harvard University, and David Daokui Li, professor of Economics at Tsinghua School of
Economics and Business in Beijing, were arguing in favour, Fareed Zakaria, CNN and editor in chief of the U.S. journal
Foreign Affairs, and Henry Kissinger, 56. U.S. Secretary of State (1973-77)
promoting “normalizing relations with China”, contested the resolution.[1] At the
beginning the audience expressed 39 Pro : 40 Contra (and 21 % undecided) in favor of the question; afterwards it turned into 38 Pro : 62
Contra. The debate does not only underline the high public significance of the
topic, it also reflects the difficulties to frame the question in a simple
yes/no answer. Mr. Li’s assertion of a strong China rejected any ambitions to
world dominance, stressing Chinese government’s ambitions to contribute to a
polycentric world, based on “harmony”. His position was close to Kissinger’s,
who also acknowledged China’s ascent, but did not expect China to be ready or
able for global leadership.[2] So
Ferguson was practically alone, taking century-long historical legacy, sheer
size of territory and population, and catching-up success not only in exports,
but also in consumption, as the main indicators of a steady rise, to be
resulting in global dominance. Ferguson’s main arguments, however, were
grounded in two developments beyond Chinese influence: First he saw the rise of
East Asia as the future global core as part of the cyclical shift of hegemony,
now returning to a world region, which for a long time had been the leading
one. Without referring to it, he took up the “Great Divergence” debate[3],
interpreting China’s rise as a shift towards a “Great convergence”. Second, he
introduced the decline of the West, comprising both the United States and the
European Union (which he simplisticly takes for
‘Europe’), as the main drivers, which make China’s rise possible. According to
Ferguson, it was not until the 2008 global economic crisis, that China was able
to shift from cheap export manufacturing to a center
of growing domestic demand and consumption. Ferguson’s observation is in line
with China’s Five Years Plan[4] and
with other official government documents and semi-official policy papers
proclaiming “Giving Priority to Enriching People”. "During the past 30
years and more, China scared world-attractive achievements in both economic and
social development, successfully entering the new development-oriented stage
from the stage of survival and upgrading from a low income country to a middle
income country. In this process, the aggregate-oriented economic development
pattern played its historic role. The trend shows that in the coming 10-15
years, China has the conditions and possibility to become a high income
country".[5]
China is holding a quarter of the world population, but only 4 % of global
consuming, the policy paper argues. Therefore it advocates shifting the focus
from investment to consume and transform China into a global consuming power.[6]
Different
from the Munk Debate audience, East Asia’s ascent,
and China’s rise to economic core, if not to global hegemony, is widely taken
as the dominant tendency in today’s world economy and geopolitics. While it is
usually associated with fear, and rejection, from western points of view[7],
observers that are critical of the West interpret it as a move towards greater
equality in wealth distribution and international relations, hopefully
contributing to a post-capitalist world, overcoming the pitfalls of capital
accumulation.[8]
Both the fearful and the wishful thinking might not be the best basis for
assessing the conditions and the restraints, resulting from successful catching
up, eventually preventing China from becoming the driving power to enact a
shift from Western hegemony to a polycentric balance of global power.
Prominent
Western sceptics, like Zakaria[9],
advocate the lack of what he calls “liberal democracy” or “constitutional
liberalism”[10],
enabling innovation and adaptability to new tasks, therefore not taking Chinese
advent as a serious challenge. They face objection from people, who rather see
the steering capacity of the political leadership (in other words: the
authoritarian character of Chinese economic reform) as a precondition for its
advantage vis-à-vis Western democracies. According to Huang Yasheng,
political scientist at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, the build up
of infrastructure that is driving national growth is the more effective the
more decision making and landownership is concentrated in the hands of the
state.[11]
Two
Harvard historians of science developed a possible scenario for the collapse of
Western civilization, which they predict to take place at the end of the 21st
century.[12]
Their alarming dystopian study, which aims at provoking counter-action today,
signals the continuity of human life after the big disaster, however. Out of
the world, which arises after mass deaths, floods and territorial restructuring
of human habitat during the “Great Collapse and Mass Migration” (dated from
2073 to 2093), a “Second People’s Republic of China” takes the lead in
stabilizing human life and international relations. We receive the information
from a Chinese historian, who set out to recount the development that led to
the disaster and enabled China to take the lead in re-establishing stability
around the year 2090. Strong political leadership accounts for one of the
qualities for humankind to resettle under a resurgent China.
The
aforementioned study advocates a change of the economic and epistemic model,
for unlimited growth is undermining human existence on earth. It is in line
with prognostic social science literature, describing the present crisis as a
final crisis of capitalism, giving way to either catastrophic scenarios or the
chance to build up a more just and sustainable, post-capitalist world at a
moment of global bifurcation. This expectation is widely spread in particular
among scientists, who follow a world-system approach that relies on cyclical
shifts of global hegemony and accumulation. [13] Again
China comes in as a symbol of hope, based on its ability to succeed and at the
same time transform vanishing Western hegemony.
This
article does not advocate hope or fear with regard to China. It listens both to
voices, predicting Chinese advent within the international division of labor (in positive and critical connotation), and to voices
that acknowledge success, but at the same time express doubts about the
prospects to translate economic catching up into long term stability,
sustainability and social integration (not necessarily based on a scenario of
permanent growth), allowing China to acquire a global role model position.[14] It
starts with a general outline of China’s departure towards market-economy in
1978, then develops the argument with the help of an empirical study of the
textile sector, and ends with a theoretical reprise.
China entering the world-economy
In his
book “Is China Buying the World?” Peter Nolan clearly shows that in spite of
considerable catching-up achievements in building up internationally
competitive firms, in promoting investment, export capacity, skills and global
sourcing and acquiring activity, China is still a developing country, if
compared to high-income countries, in particular the United States, Great
Britain, Germany, France and Japan. He goes back to the world economic crisis
of the 1970s showing the western firms’ and financial institutions’ answers to
overcome it by economic liberalization, in particular the unprecedented process
of capital concentration in each sector of the economy, resulting in a small
number of system integrators that control resources, brands, technology and
supply chains, achieving global market shares up to 100 %.[15] Less
profitable businesses are sold off or outsourced to peripheral locations, while
headquarters, R&D remain in the old cores. Although the affiliation of the
MNC to a specific state is diminishing by mergers, cooperations
overwhelmingly take place between high-income locations, incorporating
developing countries on the lower ends of the commodity chain at best.
A survey
conducted by the UK Government’s Department of Trade and Industry (DTI) in 2008
compiled the top 1400 global companies, showing that out of the total
investment in R&D 60 % took place within the top 100 firms, while the
bottom 100 firms accounted for less than 1 % of the total.[16]
Moreover, only 37 out of 1400 firms came from low and middle income countries,
which have 84 % of the world’s population; 34 of them from Brazil, Russia,
India and China (BRIC). Between 2001/2 and 2009/10 R&D investment in the
world’s top companies increased by three-fifths, rendering investment in
technical progress a key source of competitive advantage. China and others were
entering global competition at a moment of enormous concentration of Western
companies to defend and increase global lead.
When the
Chinese government and Communist Party dismissed the Maoist model of autarkist
self-reliance in 1978, outsourcing low-skill and low-wage manufacturing from
Western cores to developing countries was on top of the agenda to overcome the
crisis. By mobilizing peasants from the interior to the coastal regions through
the introduction of the “Household Responsibility System”[17] in
peasant agriculture, lifting restrictions on internal migration and the
authorization of export manufacturing zones, China was able to meet an
urgent necessity of restructuring the global commodity chain. Allowing
privatization and establishment of private firms in the consumer industries was
only one side of industrial restructuring, however. On the other side there was
the transformation of state owned companies into giant firms, aiming at meeting
Western standards of competition, in strategic sectors of the economy.[18] These
firms are state-owned and rely on public demand. While private founders, both
from the People’s Republic and the Chinese diaspora, were encouraged by low
legal barriers, cheap government credits and the absence of almost any
requirements protecting and providing social security to workers, the
government giants maintained labor protection.
However, the number of protected workers decreased by privatizations and
lay-offs, constituting the labor-force for private
hiring, but also for risking to start one’s own private business.
Table 1: China: The proportion of
different forms of ownership
|
Public Ownership |
Non-public Ownership |
|||
Year |
State-ownership |
Collective ownership |
capitalist |
individual |
|
cooperative |
Joint venture |
||||
1952 |
19.1 |
1.5 |
0.7 |
6.9 |
71.8 |
1957 |
33.2 |
56.4 |
7.6 |
0.0 |
2.8 |
1978 |
56.2 |
42.9 |
|
0.9 |
|
1997 |
41.9 |
33.9 |
24.2 |
||
2005 |
31.0 |
8.0 |
61.0 |
Source: Allan Xioajin
Ding, Shanghai University of Economics and Finance, 2011.
The table shows a considerable percentage
of collective ownership, which after 1978 underwent a transformation into
“Township and Village Enterprises” (TVEs), offering peasants the possibility to
work in nearby towns. It also shows, that after 1997 private ownerhship faced a rapid increase at the expense of
collective and state ownership.
When
assessing the role of Chinese firms in the global economy, private contract
manufacture and state-owned strategic giants show a totally different pattern.
Contract manufacture is a vulnerable sector, exposed to high pressure from the
contractors, which can only be met by the Chinese producers due to the
availability and new mobilization of cheap migrant labor,
willing to accept the crude labor-dormitory regime as
a ladder to social ascent.[19] The
contracted Chinese firm is located at the lowest end of the commodity chain,
often subcontracting further into small family enterprises. The huge demand for
migrant labor has a hoover effect on the rural
economy, both attracting fresh labor and mobilizing
family household and small agriculture in the rural areas to support migrant
workers with unpaid work.[20]
By
contrast, the state enterprise sector is relying on urban workers. Backed by
government protection, it developed to a highly competitive level. Following
the Western type of concentration, going global in order to raise capital,
improve technology and secure resources was just a question of time. Limits of
foreign investment were lifted, allowing foreign participation and inter-firm
cooperation. Nolan is listing Chinese giant firms in strategic sectors such as
power station construction, high speed trains, oil companies, banking,
aerospace, telecom equipment etc.[21] They
are related to the rest of the economy by the booming demand for
infrastructure, construction, machinery, energy, hence relying on the internal
demand of a fast growing economy. Some of the Chinese giants were able to enter
FT 500 and FORBES lists of big enterprise. Compared on the grounds of R&D
expenditures, brands and export markets in high-income countries the Chinese
state-owned firms have a low performance though.
There is
increasing interest of big Chinese firms to globalize their investment in order
to secure supply, technological cooperation and markets since the turn of the
century. China’s FDI outflows were almost absent in 2000, showing a steady rise
until 2007 ($19 billion), followed by a steep rise from 2008 to 2010 ($59
billion).[22]
Big Chinese firms began striving for mergers, acquisitions and share packages
in foreign markets.
Looking at
the absolute amount of Chinese investment in high-income countries, there is no
reason to assume, that “China is buying the world”, as suspected by fearful
commentators. China bought some mining, transport and industrial assets in
high-income countries, most prominent the take-over of IBM Personal Computer
division by Lenovo in 2005, the Swedish car company Volvo by Geely in 2010[23]
or the 35 year license agreement for the Pireus
Container Harbor by the Cosco-Group
in 2009.[24]
In the
meanwhile Western firms steadily increased their positions in China by
investing in Chinese companies, rising from $52 billion in 2002 to $106 billion
in 2010, accounting for high percentages of added value, sales and exports.[25] Among
others, major Western car producers built up joint ventures with Chinese firms
in order to profit from cheaper production costs and the vast market, provided
by an expanding middle class.[26]
Globalizing the production chain opened emerging markets to Western
acquisitions and involved local industries into transnational supply,
contracting and subcontracting chains. “Our firms build positions inside them”,
Nolan argues, referring to U.S. Secretary of Labor
(1993-97) Robert Reichs seminal articles in the
Harvard Business Review, entitled “Who is us?” (1990) and “Who is them?”
(1991), responding to the fact that the national base of U.S. industries was
replaced by international mergers and cross-national investments. Questions of
U.S. national identity against the backdrop of industrial decline also inspired
Samuel Huntington’s book “Who are we?” (2005).[27]
In 2005,
the purchase of the U.S. oil company Unilocal by the
Chinese CNOOC was stopped by appealing to national security concerns.[28]
Chinese state-owned oil companies, which are highly dependent on oil imports,
wanted to get a foot into the international oil market, which faced major
monopolistic restructuring in the late 1990s. A similar case of rejection took
place, when Chinalco was offered a strategic position
in the Australian mining company Rio Tinto in 2009. Similar ressentment
accompanied the acquisition of the French Club Mediterranée
by Fosun.[29] In
spite of the commitment to free move of capital, Western firms and their states
react by closing off their markets from Chinese acquisitions, driving them into
stock shares instead of take-overs.[30] They
also redirect Chinese investment into emerging and developing countries.
To date,
the global ownership was not turned upside down, in the contrary: While China’s
stock of outward FDI increased eightfold between 2000 and 2009, provoking media
discussion that “China is buying the world”, in fact there is still a large
deficit in China’s FDI,, inward foreign investment by far exceeding China’s
outward FDI. Moreover, China’s investment in high-income countries is
negligible: in 2009 it amounted to $27 billion, compared with Western inward
investment of $500 billion.[31] Alone
67 % of China’s outward stock of FDI went to Hongkong
and Macao in 2009.[32]
Like
inside China, the foreign investment of Chinese private manufacturers differ
from strategic state-owned firms. When private manufacture, either from the
diaspora or from the mainland, goes global, it was to relocate low-skill tasks
from China to developing countries in order to upgrade the functions that are
kept at home. In the case of textiles, by far the most important sector to go
global, this means, that spinning and weaving is kept in China, while garments
are manufactured in neighboring Asian countries or in
other parts of the Global South. Initiative and inter-firm communication
depended to a high degree on diaspora Chinese, paving the way for further
private investment, when labor costs in China went up
after the reforms of the labour regulations in 2006.
Foreign investments
in infrastructure, transport and construction are carried out by state owned
big enterprise, eventually in cooperation with private partners. Provided
without conditionality, Chinese companies often are more attractive than
Western competitors. Conversely, they often bring their own workers as part of
a full package, meeting critique of disregarding local labor
markets, sparking anti-Chinese feelings.[33]
Foreign investment does not primarily aim at returns, but at securing raw
materials, agricultural commodities and intermediate inputs, access to
technological upgrading as well as to selling markets. Networking is embedded
into strategic considerations of supporting China’s place in an international
division of labor that more and more orients towards
China.
Victor Krasilshchikov’s comparative explorations about East and
South East Asian Tigers’ and some Latin American states’ catching-up experience
serves as a useful corrective to premature interpretations of China’s rise to
core, not to speak of hegemonic or post-hegemonic ambitions. Studying the first
and second tier East and South East Asian Tigers’ development trajectories, Krasilshchikov does not see arguments that support an East
Asian renaissance. In spite of different political systems, these projects were
characterized by the dependency on the global cores. By following the
development pattern of the advanced industrial states, they achieved industrial
and technological development. Semi-peripheral success led to a series of
traps, however. Whenever success was achieved, it took place in sectors, which
had lost lead and therefore were assigned to move into peripheral locations,
while the cores in the meanwhile had moved on a new track. According to Krasilshchikov, the conservative character of
modernization, carried through with authoritarian means, guaranteed that cheap labor power was mobilized into export production, thus
fulfilling the high income, or high end producers’ interest in lowering costs
and securing supply. Rising inequality was a condition of success, at the same
time blocking the spillover of growth to peripheral
regions and broader layers of the population. This is why the initial impetus
of catching-up, promoted both by national endeavours and global product cycles,
did not allow the semi-peripheral economies to transform into cores. In the
contrary, as soon as they had reached a certain level of industrial success,
they fell back, because local elites were reluctant to overcome social and
regional imbalances.[34] The
availability of cheap labor prevented the
implementation of more sophisticated techniques, blocking development on a high
level equilibrium, depriving educated middle-classes from expected and promised
social advancement.
It is
doubtful to compare China with small, politically dependent states instead of
looking at the role of China in re-assessing regional power, which it had
exercised for centuries. It is still open, if China will fall into the same
traps, as the large Latin American countries and the Asian Tigers did before.
There are good reasons to assume, that China is different because of historical
legacy, size and timing, and will be able to overcome the limits that slowed
down the Tigers’ advent, not only by activating her huge internal resources,
but also by establishing new types of international cooperation with other
emerging projects in the near and far Global South. China might serve as the
intermediating hub, eventually overcoming, against Krasilshchikov’s
assumption, the limits of conservative modernization.
Textiles and garments reflecting
reform and restructuring
This
chapter focuses the private manufacturing sector, in particular textiles and
garments.[35]
After a short summary, depicting the transition from global contract
manufacturing to high end production searching control of the commodity chain,
allowing raising income and consumption for bigger parts of the Chinese
population, the prospects and limits of high end production will be discussed
on the grounds of a field study, carried out in the Shanghai region in 2011.
The results will be analysed against the competing interpretations of hegemonic
rise or traps to modernization that might even restrict the prospect of China’s
transition into economic core. Finally the question is raised of whether or not
using core – periphery models may help to grasp China’s shifting position in
the world economy.
From
Contract Manufacture to Global Player
Textiles
and garments were among the first sectors, which underwent closure of state
companies or privatization. After restructuring in 1993, the state share of
textile/garments fell from 98 to 20 %, closing or privatizing companies and
laying off 1.5 million workers.[36] At
the same time, former employees were encouraged to greenfield strategies, first
in special Export Production Zones (EPZs), later on extended to coastal cities,
then to entire coastal provinces.[37] Huge
industrial zones with never-ending factory compounds mushroomed, housing both
production halls and dormitories. The years 1980-2006 can be regarded as the
period of contract manufacturing.[38]
Private
consumer industries were supplying Western and Japanese companies with Cut Make
Trim (CMT) or Original Equipment Manufacture (OEM) – simple, labor-intense operations at the low end of the commodity
chain. Labor was provided by migrant workers, who
were allowed to leave their home villages, but did not obtain household
registration at their work place.[39] They
worked long hours for low wages, and control included the dormitories provided
by the company.[40]
Outsourcing to contractors allowed foreign customers easy cost savings, on the
one side fuelled from surplus value from factory labor,
on the other side backed by the transfer value from non-paid labor, performed by the migrants’ home families. Demand
rose steadily contributing to China’s rising trade surplus with the United
States of $ 1,6 billion in 2011, stabilizing the U.S. budget by the purchase of
U.S. treasuries. From the 1990s onwards, production chains in the textile
sector faced a transition from “production-driven” to “buyer-driven” impetus:
while in the former companies relocated manufacturing to subsidiaries, the
latter was dominated by global retail and brand owning companies, sourcing from
various independent contractors.[41]
The
out-phasing of the World Textile Agreement in 2004 accelerated sourcing in and
outsourcing to China, because it ended the system of export quotas, set up in
the framework of GATT in 1974 by the Multi-Fibre Agreement, followed by the
World Textile Agreement in 1994 in order to protect Western textile industry.
Until then, Western country-wise import quota had opened developing countries
windows of opportunity for exporting to high-income countries. When quotas were
abolished, China’s manufacturing capacity had a “hoover effect” on global
buyers, who now preferred to shop one stop in China instead of including
various smaller and often less reliable contractors. It encouraged “global buyers” turning to
China and make use of the complete commodity chain, offered by Chinese contractors
and agents. [42]
In the
meanwhile the Chinese government had changed its objectives. Simple export
manufacturing was declared being overcome and new strategies for upgrading
China’s position in the commodity chain were announced. The shift from outward
processing for foreign contractors towards controlling the more rewarding high
end operations aims at allowing China to
become a high-income country, “giving priority to enriching people” instead of
“global buyers” and western consumers, and gradually replace export by domestic
markets.[43]
It goes
without saying that the implementation of a new strategy takes time and
requires transitions, in which old and new type enterprise overlaps. The
political primacy, held by the Communist Party and the government, was about to
support change, however. Just as they had opened the field for private company
foundations by allowing employers to fully exploit their workers, they now
introduced requirements for labor regulation, minimum
wages and social security, raising the income, the social position and the
purchasing power of the workers.[44]
Regulation can also be seen as a response to the huge amount of labor protests, involving millions of workers.[45]
Conflict resolution became institutionalized, allowing the government to use
workers’ protest to make employers adapt to the new situation.[46]
Factory owners were not only pushed to upgrade their production, but they also
faced a cost explosion, resulting from wage increases, lower working hours and
employers’ contributions to social security. At the end, they were pushed to
give up low technology production and move into more profitable activities.
Banks stopped to give cheap credits for contract manufacturing at all.
Upgrading also was to affect the textile and garment sector by overcoming the
low-skill, low-wage, low-end model of CMT and OEM manufacture and replace it by
Original Design Manufacture (ODM) or, at best, by Original Brand Manufacture
(OBM).[47]
The light
textile industry should strengthen environmental protection and quality safety,
strengthen corporate brand building and improve technological equipment level”.[48] For
the textile industry the overall directive of the 12th Five Years Plan foresaw
to “Promote the industrialization and application of hi-tech fibers, and new-generation functional and differential fibers. Accelerate the development of industrial textile
products. Promote the localization of high-end looms and accessories. Support
the recycling of old and waste textile products.”[49] In
other words, privatly owned Chinese consumer
industries were to deliver higher added value with the help of product
innovation (new products), process innovation (new technologies) and logistics
(command of commodity chains).
Industrial
statistics prove evidence that China was able to enter new sectors and move up
the chain, hence reaching a position to “catch the value”. As a consequence,
textile and garment industries’ share in total industrial production decreased
from 20 % (1990) to 8 % (2010).[50]
Likewise, output and labor productivity increased.
The Five Year plan meticulosly listed the
strategic emerging sectors., like new generation IT, energy saving and
recycling, biological industry, rail traffic and aviation equipment,
satellites, new generation nuclear and solar energy, photovoltaic and others,
which should put China on a technology intensive and knowledge based growth
track.[51]
However, the textile sector still contributes important shares to industrial
added value and employment. Textile and garment are themselves target of
restructuring, moving towards high end, skilled, technology-intense, value
creating activities, including build up and control of commodity chains with
company branding.
Table 2 shows growth rates as compared to the
declining rates in the United States.
Table 2: Textile, Garment & Leather: China in
Comparison with United States
|
Textile 1998 |
Growth 1998 -2005 |
Garment & Leather 1998 |
Growth 1998 - 2005 |
Output value, Mio US-$ China U. S. |
52, 559 91,387 |
+ 193% - 33% |
38,722 74,960 |
+ 166% - 58% |
Added value, Mio US-$ ..China ..U.S. |
12,288 28,118 |
+ 222% - 24,8% |
9,001 14,933 |
+ 221% - 48% |
Per capita added value US-$ China U.S. |
2123 42219 |
+ 215% + 33% |
2750 41412 |
+ 83% + 20% |
Labour force: large companies, Mio persons ..China 2006 ..U.S. 2004 |
6,25 Mio (2006) 405.000 (2004) |
|
6,23 Mio 332.000 |
|
Profits, Mio US-$ ..China ..U.S. |
2,038 (2002) 2,343 (2002) |
+ 217% (02-06) + 4,6% (02-06) |
2,038 (2002) 6,492 (2002) |
+ 17% (2002-06) + 14% (2002-06) |
Source: Yin Xingming (2009): China catches up with the U.S. as the
world’s largest manufacturer, in: China
Economist Nov/Dec. 2009, 20-30.
Since 2006
there was a high legal and financial pressure on contract manufacture owners in
coastal areas to follow the new plan directives. As a consequence, hundreds of
companies were not able to comply, resulting in a high rate of bankruptcies.[52] A
large number of companies was able to survive along the old pattern of low wage
low end manufacturing, however. In many other cases successful restructuring
took off, introducing new products, new technologies and new steering logistics
into the textile and garment sector.
Sewing and the production of
knit-wear do not offer big potentials to raise labour-productivity, therefore
they are facing outsourcing from the coastal provinces to the Chinese interior,
or to Vietnam, Cambodia, Laos, Indonesia, or Sub-Saharan Africa, where labor is much cheaper. Conversely, spinning, weaving and
knit-weaving allow to introduce advanced technologies and high end products
transforming the textile sector into a capital- and technology-intensive one.
Those textile firms in the east that
are able to upgrade their position in the commodity chain by covering high end
production, branding and merchandising, by improving material quality,
machinery, working skills and process control and eventually outsource
labour-intensive productions to cheaper sites will be able to meet the
challenge of restructuring. We can find this type of company in the spinning
and in the weaving sector, delivering highly qualified yarns and fabrics for
fashion wear, home textiles and technical applications.
Restructuring
textile and garments, led to spatial re-arrangements, both within China and on
the international scale. Until recently, export manufacturing was concentrated
in the coastal provinces in the East and South of China. Upgrading efforts led
to the outsourcing of labor-intense operations into
the Chinese interior. The call to “Go West” was deliberately expressed in
policy papers, and it was linked with government strategies, both offering
incentives and putting pressure on local governments to follow it. So China’s
large internal peripheries were mobilized. At this moment, the household
registration system (hukou)
once more turned out to be a useful instrument assigning people to a specific
place. Enlarging eligibility for migrants to the coastal zones could be useful
to attract and settle skilled labor, while keeping
the unskilled migrant workers in a temporary, unsecured position including the
possibility to redirect them to their home villages or to the growing
urbanisations in the interior.[53] In
the case of Chongqing, the booming urban region of the interior, the local
government was authorized to award 1 million hukou-registrations to legalize
the permanent residence of newly arriving migrants.[54]
“Go South”
was another strategy, making use of OEM supply chains in developing countries
to deliver low skill components. Chinese companies started to set up
subsidiaries in Third World Countries subcontracting local producers for
further outsourcing demands. In fact, Chinese entrepreneurs, many of them
members of the Chinese diaspora, set up production sites in developing
countries already since the 1990s. Textile and garment production abroad was a
possibility to benefit from the host country’s export quota to Western markets
(“quota-hopping”). After the liberalization of the global textile trade in
2004/05, outsourcing entered a new stage. According to the strategy of
technological upgrading within China, Chinese companies made use of cheap
production sites abroad, supplying them with fabrics made in China, while relocating
simpler and low skill tasks to South-East Asia or Africa. In the case of
Sub-Saharan Africa, raw African cotton was imported to China, where fabrics
were manufactured and sent to Africa for sewing and assembling, thus
constituting a triangular manufacturing circle. In Least Developed Sub-Saharan
countries the majority of garment factories belong to Chinese (diaspora)
owners; in South Africa, where the domestic market is served by local
entrepreneurs, they control the export sector.[55] Under
the African Growth and Opportunity Act (AGOA)[56] these
garments enjoy a duty-free entry to the United States; LDCs like Lesotho, one
of the leading participants of the program, were given a third country dispense
clause from rules of origin, allowing a “one stage transformation” (instead of
at least two stages) in Africa from imported fabrics.[57] As a
consequence of this alleged incentive, domestic Sub-Saharan textile production
was completely displaced or discouraged. The beneficiaries of the program are
retailers and consumers in the United States as well as the network of Chinese
companies and their African subsidiaries.
Relocating
labor-intense operations to the interior, to
South-East Asian or to African countries, was to allow the highly developed
Chinese coastal provinces to foster quality improvement and brand development.
By achieving control over the commodity chain, they were able to offer a
finished product to the customer without relying on “global buyers”.
Foreign
companies’ sourcing strategies adapted to the new situation. For example: In
the aftermath of the World Textile Agreement in 2004, several European textile
& garment industry associations had founded the China-Europe
Textile-Alliance C.E.T.A. in Shanghai.
They set up a joint office for establishing direct contacts to Chinese
companies.[58]
Until then contacts with Chinese suppliers were rather built up with the help
of agencies, held in Hongkong. The new institution
reflected the increasing significance of China‘s role in contract manufacturing
for Western companies. Only a few years later, France, Spain, and Austria
withdrew from C.E.T.A. One of the reasons was to be found in the new landscape
of global manufacturing, in which Chinese companies more and more oversee the
complete process of development, production, and finishing. The demand for
intermediaries had diminished.
While
contract manufacture followed “global buyers’” orders, who market the finished
product under their own brand, Original Brand Manufacturing (OBM) replaced
foreign by domestic brands.[59] Only
few of them gained reputation on international markets yet. Another efficient
way of upgrading to OBM status was through purchasing foreign brand companies[60], thus
fulfilling the call for “high tech and fashion”, proclaimed by then Party Leader
Jiang Zemin at the 16th meeting of CPCh
conference.[61]
Eastern
China textile sector facing limits of upgrading
After the
Pearl River delta, the first industrial cluster to specialize on export
manufacturing in 1980, the Shanghai urban region as well as Jiangsu and Zhejiang provinces were next to pop up. The Yangzi
River Delta became open costal zone in 1985.[62] The
region has a long history of cotton and silk manufacturing. In the wake of the Opium
wars 1842 and 1860, Shanghai became a colonial enclave, housing the first
textile mills in China. In 1930 200.000 out of 285.000 workers were employed in
textile factories, 1960 the number went up to 550.000. Until the beginning of
“Reform and Opening”, state owned textile and garment companies were located in
central urban industrial districts. After the 1990s central areas faced new
rapid development, replacing old factories or transforming them into
exhibition, shopping and restaurant facilities. Industry was relocated into the
outskirts of the Shanghai region, or to the neighbouring provinces. [63]
In all
towns you can find huge industrial areas with hundreds and thousands of factory
compounds. A part of the early foundations of the 1990s and 2000s today faces
serious problems, hundreds had to close down. Others are successful examples of
restructuring.
A field
study carried out in July and August 2011 in six companies illustrates the
broad variety of business models, coexisting in Eastern China. They mirror the
transformations, carried out in the textile sector, and the challenges to come.
Visited companies:[64]
-
C1
Xishengyu Jishan (Shanghai),
garment CMT for European and Japanese firms
-
C2
Danfeng Haining (Zhejiang),
fully integrated sock knitting production for German buyers
-
C3
Jiale Jishan (Shanghai),
fully integrated production line for knit and sportswear, subsidiary locations
in the Chinese interior and abroad
-
C4
Dual Nanjing (Jiangsu), tire cord weaving company, Korean subsidiary
-
C5
Colon Jiangyin (Jiangsu), airbag weaving and sewing
company, Korean subsidiary
-
C6
Chindo, Wai Gao Quiao Tax Free Zone (Shanghai), Selling and Service Centre
of Dornier, a German producer of high quality weaving machines
The textile and garment sector is
showing a broad variety of company models, fulfilling different functions in
the global commodity chain, comprising fully integrated production lines as
well as component productions, ranging from simple contract manufacture (CMT,
OEM) to higher value adding functions including design (ODM) or, more recently,
even to the development of own brands (OBM), challenging Western brands on
domestic and export markets. The visited companies reflect the bifurcation.
C1 and C2 represent extended
workbenches for Western and Japanese buyers, they are likely to face closing
down. C1 is specialized on apparel sewing, C2 on sock knitting.
Xishengyu garment factory in Jinshan
(C1), founded in the early 1990s by a former tailor, reduced its workforce from
1000 in 2003 to 300-400 in 2011. The owner can hardly cope with the rising
costs for labour, which increase by approx. 20 % per year in Shanghai, and more
so by the rising contributions to workers’ social security, which increased by
twenty times between 2006 and 2011. His contractors are not willing to come up
for the higher cost, rather going to relocate sourcing to cheaper places. The
owner reacted by moving production to a smaller and cheaper site, planning the
closure of the company at the moment of his retirement. His son already moved
to another business.
The owners of the Danfeng sock factory in Haining
(C2), founded in 2000 by a young couple without any entrepreneurial and textile
experience, are equally aware of the tense situation. German super-market chains,
on whose distribution their production relies, still fill their order books,
guaranteeing work for 100 employees. But they feel the pressure on the price,
and pass it over to their workers, who have to work over-time, regardless of
the new labour regulations. Asked, if her son would take over, the owner seemed
surprised. This question had not yet come into her mind. Product cycles in the
sock industry are too short to plan a succession. If small and medium enterpreneurs (SME) in low skill and low wage contract
manufacturing started in the right moment, with the right contacts to party and
government officials, they were able to make a quick start and enter big
business. A big majority of SME factory-owners’ carriers end because of the
rapid turnover of the product cycle. If they are not able to move up the chain
or find a new niche product, their status as entrepreneurs might not be safe.
The high-end sports and leisure ware
company in Jinshan (C3), represents the way the
government is planning to restructure the textile sector. Jiale
was founded in 1993 as a private company, enjoying high support and protection
from the local government. It comprised departments for knit-weaving fabrics,
which are processed to final products in the cutting and sewing departments.
The products are ordered, purchased and sold under the brand of the buyers’
firms, hence corresponding the OEM type of outsourcing. Show room and video
performance show a broad variety of well-known Western brands from Tommy
Hilfiger to The Northface.
When profits diminished because of
rising labor cost, the management introduced a design
department, hence increasing the company’s control over the production line and
expanding into more know-how-intensive operations, attracting buyers on a more
profitable basis (= ODM). According to the General Manager, they plan to start
developing products, branded under their own name. In the meanwhile the
emphasis is put on raising the quality of fibers,
e.g. by purchasing special yarns from the Austrian-Chinese Lenzing-Nanjing
Fibres Company. Relocation is carried out in order to transfer labor-intensive processes into the interior, where a
subsidiary was opened in Anhui province in 2007. In 2011 another subsidiary
started in Indonesia. By then the workforce comprised 5000 in Jinshan, 3000 in Anhui and 2000 workers in Indonesia,
combining different qualification, labor and social
security regimes and costs. This strategy is supposed to support the upgrading
of the Shanghai locations, allowing the company to enter into a better position
to control and profit from the textile commodity chain.
Another type of upgrading of the
textile industry is pursued by C4 and C5, two Korean owned producers of
technical textiles (tires, airbags). Compared to clothing and home textiles,
technical textiles represent a highly sensitive branch of the textile sector,
facing high quality and safety requirements. So C4 and C5 represent the high
value side of textiles. The Korean companies chose China for the relocation of
production both for cost saving and obtaining access to the Chinese market. As
Eastern China hosts major factories for car production in cooperation with
European, U.S., Japanese or South Korean companies, the automotive sector is
encouraging investment in supplying industries.
Dual (C4) and Colon (C5) deliver
their products, tire-cord and airbags, to tire and car companies. The
headquarters are situated in Korea, with subsidiary plants in China. This
allows making use of the wage differential, which still saves 70 % compared to
Korea according to the management. Cheap wages are combined with a strategy of
using high tech machines in order to meet the standards of the international
buyers. High tech machinery in the weaving sector is first of all linked with
German and Swiss companies, specialized in the most advanced spinning, weaving
and knitting technologies. These machines are much more expensive than Chinese,
Korean and Japanese ones, but allow achieving results not available with
ordinary device. They require special training for the workers. This
arrangement is supposed to open new markets for European machine builders. I
had the opportunity to visit the two Korean companies as a member of the
service team of a leading German producer of automatic looms, Dornier, with
headquarters and machine building located at Lake Constance. At first sight,
technical problems how to handle certain operations, to avoid time losses and
damaged goods and to obtain permanent quality were on the agenda. Very soon
they turned out to be structural problems, resulting from a basic
contradiction: When the Korean managers complained about defects of the
machinery, the German technician stressed the necessity to invest in training
of the personnel and careful maintenance of the machines, otherwise the
expansive investment would not be rewarding. Quite openly he addressed the
working conditions, the over length of the working hours and the lacking
investment in attaching skilled workers to the company. Working hours were up
to 12 hours daily, 6 days a week. Under these conditions, workers did not stay
in the company for a long time.[65]
Once trained, they took with them the knowledge and the experience they had
gathered with the new machines.
Chindo (C6) is the service center of Dornier. The upgrading of the Chinese textile
industry offers new markets for western suppliers of machinery and intermediate
inputs. They can help Chinese or foreign companies producing in China to enter
high quality production.
Studying the German machine company
that is supplying textile companies all over the world with special automatic
looms, allowed observing the transfer of knowledge. Dornier started to sell to
Chinese textile firms from the 1980s onwards, first to state owned companies,
later more and more to private ones. Installation, training and service were
organized from the German headquarters, until trade and service subsidiaries
were set up in the main selling markets. The training and service company
covering East and South East Asia, Chindo, was founded
in Shanghai in 2005. It is managed by a German director, responsible for
technical and commercial affairs, and a Chinese executive, responsible for
administrative and financial issues. All customers are invited to send their
staff to be trained in the training centre. Instead of sending German
technicians into Chinese companies, the training is carried out by Chinese
technicians, ready to demonstrate handling and maintaining of a sensitive
technology in the center as well as on site. We face
a transfer of technology, which leads from the German machine factory to the
Chinese textile company – mediated and accompanied by Chindo,
where German knowledge is transferred first to Chinese trainers and in a second
step to Chinese workers. As I learned, Chinese – or as pointed out above Korean
– companies still underestimate the importance of training and education. The
future is likely to bring greater awareness for the benefits of “social
upgrading”, however. More so, Chinese manufacturers might discover, that producing
high quality textile machines can lead a next cycle of upgrading. In this case
textile could follow garment in its move to the West, pushing garment out of
China, while new sectors might completely replace textiles in the coastal
areas.
Move towards a Global Economic Core?
The field-study allows the following
conclusions.
1 We face the dislocation of low end
manufacture from the coastal provinces to the Chinese interior and to
developing countries. Contract manufacturers in the dynamic coastal areas are
likely to close down, or to give way to technology-intense production, brand
development and high added value operations on the high end of the commodity
chain, both within and beyond the textile and garment sector.
2 For a while small and medium low
value contract manufacture enterprises, like C1 and C2, will keep operating,
supplying western buyers and retailers with cheap fashion. In the long run they
represent an outmoded model that will disappear from Eastern China, leaving
these companies without successors.
3 Textile upgrading offers new
export markets for European (German, Swiss, Italian) machine producing
companies. Hence hierarchies between old industrial cores and emerging markets
are reproduced on a new level, redirecting the benefits of successful
technological improvement in China to European high tech machinery producers.
Process upgrading simultaneously reflects success and limits of catching up.
Instead of a global rebalancing, a new technological gap opens up.
4 Outsourcing labor-intense
operations, in the case of textiles namely cutting, sewing and assembling of
garments (CMT) into low wage regions, inserts fresh cheap labor
into the commodity chain. Advancements of the coastal provinces into core
positions rest upon the peripheralization of other
regions. These regions contribute to the overall improvement, but they do so at
the expense of their own, regional upgrading.
5 Moreover, the observations in C4
and C5 show the difficulties in putting process upgrading into practice in the
coastal regions themselves. High tech textile production requires
qualifications, which can hardly be realized under the conditions of a
management, which still reflects the labor regime of
contract manufacturing: low wage, low skill, high turnover. While managers and
owners concentrate their efforts on new machinery, they neglect the human
capital side of technological upgrading: the necessity to train and motivate
their workers. Saving on wages and social benefits still lurks, preventing the
potential productivity gains from new technology to transform into sustainable
results. So even the very limited goal of reaching core standards in high
quality material weaving is not yet achieved.
6 C6, the selling and service outpost
of German machinery producer, on the one side mirrors the ongoing western
dominance, accompanying Chinese textile upgrading. Machinery is produced in
Germany, the Shanghai subsidiary only taking care of sales, service and
training. Dornier’s profit relies on the successful implementation of the
expensive, sensitive machinery in Chinese firms, however. Therefore they insist
on training their customers’ workers, hence contributing to the rise of a
well-trained, self-conscious workforce, insisting on social ascent and rising
income. It will be a question of time, until machinery production will also be
moving to China, and Chinese research and development will spill over into this
sector.
To sum up, the case study confirms
the sceptical voices doubting China’s rise to a new global core. China’s
upgrading is not (yet) achieved: It remains a declared goal; reality is still
contrasting with development plan claims. However, the observations also
deliver arguments, showing the ambitious attempts to restructure and transform
China from a low end contract manufacturer to a high skill and high value
producing location controlling the commodity flows not only in China, but also
on a global scale.
At that instant, the prospects of a
hegemonic shift come on the agenda. A transition to a global core is a sine qua
non for such a shift. However, a global core status does not necessarily go
along with a hegemonic shift. Discussing the likelihood, conditions and
outcomes of a transformation of the global order, we have to transcend the
realm of upgrading and catching-up.
Hegemonic shift or multi-polar world?
Discussing “China” in the West, is
highly emotional. Hopeful and fearful projections often obscure the picture,
neglecting the fact that China still is a developing country, albeit with fast
growing cities, dynamic emerging regions, a rising middle-class, exploding
regional and social imbalances and a government, steered by the Communist
Party, which accompanies the internal transformation with increasing economic
and political attempts to make China an acknowledged and accepted international
player. This goes hand in hand with the reassertion and the export of China’s
cultural heritage.
Understanding China’s potential to
shift hegemonies requires a historical and a geopolitical background. Different
from most other emerging, former Third World countries, China’s attempts to
catch up and become a global core builds on its historical role as the leading
economic and cultural power before the rise of British and U.S. hegemony.
Re-orientation, after more than 150 years of political subordination and
economic peripheralization, would just restore a
previous self-reliant position. Would it, at the same time, represent a
hegemonic shift, making China – or a Chinese led alliance of Global South
states – succeed U.S. hegemony?
The debate is divided about whether
the capitalist world-system is able or not to be rejuvenated by the take-over
of a Chinese hegemon. Renewal would allow China to continue building up its
industrial capacity (1990-2007/08) into a new cycle, by then transforming the
initial dependency from Western impetus into the capacity to self-reliant
R&D, setting new standards in product and process innovation within the
next 25 years.[66] This
timing roughly fits into the pattern of Kondratiev-cycles,
claiming that the 5th Kondratiev would not
only drive China towards a global core, but equally promote its hegemonic peak.
Fig. 3: Kondratiev cycles
Source: http://de.wikipedia.org/wiki/Kondratjew-Zyklus,
7.1.2013
Fig. 4: Kondratiev cycles and hegemony
Hegemon |
Kondratiev A-phase |
Kondratieff
B-phase |
Hegemon |
GB up |
1790-1820 Textiles |
1820-1850 |
GB peak |
GB
maturity |
1850-1873 rail
roads, steel |
1873-1896 |
GB decline |
U.S. up |
1896-1914 electro,
chemistry, food |
1914-1945 |
US peak |
US
maturity |
1945-1973 mass
consumer goods, automobiles, petro-chemistry |
1973-1990 |
US decline |
China up |
1990-2008 Building
up industrial capacity |
2008-2030? Transforming
dependent into leading capacity, setting standards |
China
peak? |
China
maturity? |
|
|
China
decline? |
Kondratiev-cycles or “long waves of economic
growth” do not sufficiently take into account the effects of expansion and
contraction on the spatial arrangement of core and periphery on a regional and
on a global scale. Moreover, regional shifts in core-periphery relations are
also reflected by secular cycles of hegemony, related to the “long waves”. Both
models are highly structural and there are good reasons not to over-emphasize
their significance. However, they may serve as hypotheses, against which
empirical findings may be tested.[67]
Other voices, in compliance with China’s officials reclaiming the
peaceful character of their global ambitions aiming at a polycentric world,
reject the idea of a next hegemonic cycle within the framework of the
capitalist world-system.[68]
In spite of different lines of argumentation, they are convinced, that the
regenerative potential, which is necessary to supply a new upswing with
sufficient natural resources and human labor power,
is exhausted and a renewal can only take place, if the next world-order is
based on sustainability and social justice. They speak of the beginning of a
post-capitalist, and post-hegemonic era, following the on-going decline of U.S.
hegemony. Giovanni Arrighi has emphatically
postulated that China will be the leading power of a new world order. Instead
of exercising hegemony, he argues, China will lead on the basis of a strong political
system, based on market relations instead of capital accumulation.[69]
While the hegemonic cycle-based model does not put into question the continuity
of the existing capitalist world-system, Arrighi, Wallerstein and others argue on the assumption of a final
crisis, marking the end of a long systemic cycle, beginning with the rise of
global capitalism in the long 16th century, now attaining the end of
capitalism as a historical system: They do not see any further potential for
the capitalist world-system to overcome its present structural crisis. The
post-capitalist model does not explicitly claim a permanent Chinese leadership,
but definitely evokes the end of the expansionist model of capital
accumulation, carried out by the West. China is attributed the potential to
lead the transition into a future world-order.
Both scenarios are highly structural
and speculative. At the same time, they are realistic, each being aware, that
the decline of U.S. hegemony would open a period of competing great powers, old
cores striving to maintain, new ones to achieve a globally leading position,
whether this position would open a new hegemonic cycle of the capitalist
world-system or a post-hegemonic Chinese-led market-economy. They also agree
that the present conflicts that mirror the hegemonic crisis of the U.S. might
either be overcome, or give way to a permanent chaos, eventually changing the
conditions for human life on the planet in a way, which is difficult to
conceive today. Oreskes and Conway’s dystopia helps envisioning,
equally suggesting that China will take the lead, albeit after a horrifying
scenario of a climate collapse. [70]
For the moment we leave utopias and
dystopias to film[71]
and literature.[72]
Instead, we test China’s formation as a core, looking for indicators for a
hegemonic capitalist renewal on the one side and a polycentric post-capitalist
scenario on the other side.
Hegemonic symptoms accompanying
China’s formation as a core
There is accelerating evidence of
Chinese global acquisitions (mines, infrastructure, traffic hubs, raw
materials, food stuff), securing the supply of China’s growing economy and
feeding its population. Strong western resistance against China acquiring
ownership of western companies illustrates the old cores’ ambitions to block
specific take-overs, neither speaking with one voice nor being able to stop
their advance, however.
China is promoting the build-up of
independent financial institutions, both Chinese ones and with other BRICS
partners, eventually replacing the U.S.-Dollar by Yuan Renmimbi
or a currency basket. Increasing South-South cooperation, along with a rising
internal market, will à la longue withdraw the financial support for the
U.S.-Dollar, at present exercised by holding U.S. treasuries. Withdrawing its
credit will end the support China has given to the declining U.S. in exchange
for an open export market. Strengthening internal demand as well as non-western
export markets would replace reliance on U.S. demand, while complying with U.S.
claims to promote re-industrialization.
There is multiple evidence for a
cultural reassertion, based on historical legacy, culture, literature, spread
of Chinese philosophy and language. At the same time China is facing rapid
Westernization, and it is still an open question, if the Chinese will be able
to control acculturation without losing their traditions. Chinese cultural
strength is entering a sacred Western sphere by insisting on a Chinese
interpretation of capitalism, replacing “democracy” by “harmony.”.
Last but not least, China is
entering the arm’s race. Compared to old grand powers, it is still a wharf.
Blaming China to be aggressive, serves as a pretext to justify the
militarization of the Pacific region by former colonial powers, the United
States and its regional allies.[73]
Nevertheless, China’s global rise goes hand in hand with its growing
international economic presence. Western embargo politics against Russia,
following the conflict about Ukraine’s entering the EU association agreement,
will strengthen South-South cooperations. Russia will
rather turn to China, overcoming its fear to undergo Chinese dominance, to
compensate for EU sanctions, and Brazil, Argentina and South Africa might
profit from the rising demand, fostered by the Russian ban on European food imports.
Economic wars contribute to armament, drawing China into a competition, which
might turn out to be a burden for its economic and social ambitions, however.
Post-capitalist symptoms
accompanying China’s formation as a core
If we believe the Communist Party of
China, the present transformation will lead to the unfolding of “socialism” in
2049, 100 years after the foundation of the People’s Republic. This assertion
can hardly impact serious scholarship. However, it reminds us of the primacy of
politics, exercized by the party over the process of
transformation. Western scholarly
assumptions often do not comply with Chinese perceptions.
Post-capitalist symptoms are equally
attributed to China by western scholars. Orientalizing interpretations of China
for being static, backward and despotic, which had dominated Chinese studies
for a long time, were overcome, pointing out the strong position,
sophistication and effectiveness of China throughout history, only set out of
function from the Opium Wars 1842 to the Revolution of 1949. Kenneth Pomeranz, Andre Gunder Frank,
Kaoru Sugihara, Bin Wong and others, also referred to as the “Californian
School”, conceived a non-eurocentric approach to
China, contributing to the estimation of China’s progress and high level of
development, preceding and exceeding European states until the 18th
century.[74] With
his book “Adam Smith in Bejing” Giovanni Arrighi topped the Californian school.
Arrighi refers to Fernand Braudel’s definition of capitalism as a specific expression
of market economy, based on monopolizing markets by states who bind public
interest to those of capitalists, when he defines China’s historical system to
be a “non-capitalist market-economy”, but not a capitalist society.[75]
The present system of China builds up on this historical legacy, re-introducing
capitalist elements, but without subordinating state interest to capital.
Observing the rapid commodification of the Chinese society, increasing the
scope of activities for investors while limiting poor and working classes
participation, may evoke different interpretations, however.
Being trained in a Western, Marxist
understanding of state – capital relations in the world-system, the
hybridization of socialist and capitalist elements that Arrighi
suggests is hard to assess. Equally, liberal observers, who take capitalist
relations as a basic universal mechanism of market-society, can hardly cope
with. Conversely, postcolonial approaches plea not to subordinate non-Western
societies to Western criteria. In the Chinese context, this requires evaluating
a number of major terms and concepts. In particular, Chinese historiography
suggests interpretations of “hegemony” and “periphery”, which diverge from
Western definitions. The Chinese way of inter-linking the nation states of East
Asia through a Chinese center allowed sharing common
principles, values and norms, bridging hegemony and polycentrism. Moreover, in
the Chinese context, the term periphery stands for far distance from the center; it is not necessarily subordinated to the core,
which rather invests into its peripheries than extracts from them.[76]
In front of these considerations, we
can only suggest an open out-come. It is possible that the former hegemon and
its Western allies resist the challenges of the Global South, and block
transition. Some authors claim that this resistance is meant to promote a shift
from U.S. American hegemony towards an American global empire.[77]
The restauration of a “New American Century” may take place in compliance with
European partners, or against them, as the Ukraine – Russia case demonstrates.[78]
Another tentative outcome is a new imperialism, set up by China.[79]
Last but not least there is the option of a new multi-polar world-society,
mediated by a consolidated China.
Core and Periphery reconsidered
Looking at China, shows a broad
variety in which cores and peripheries occur. These variations apply to
different periods of history, hence represent a sequence. Likewise, they refer
to different contexts at a given time, hence show synchronicity.
During Mao’s rule (1949-1976),
socialist China refrained from being assessed on an international scale by
putting the emphasis on strengthening internal developments, replacing the
notion of “catching up” by the vision of “great leaps forward”. Although
showing a low level of measurable economic performance because of embargo and
self- isolation, the country can neither be regarded as core nor as periphery.
In the eyes of the Chinese leadership, China was perceived as a center, carrying forward the imperial tradition under
different political banners, however. China also was a center
for political movements, following or promoting the Maoist path of development
all over the world.
With the shift from Maoism to “Reform
and Opening” in 1978, China underwent a process of peripheralization:
This finding refers to the external impetus to serve as a cheap work bench for
Western companies, allowing to overcome the global economic crisis by
incorporating new sources of externalizing costs and appropriating values. It
underestimates the agency of the CPCh to adapt to the
global demand for cheap and informalized labor, while maintaining state control over foreign
investment and strategic key sectors of the economy in the process of
reintegration into the world-economy. Mobilizing migration from the
country-side to the coastal provinces designates the interior as a source of
value appropriation, hence introducing spatial peripheralization
into a relationship that was governed by administrative regulations instead of
market forces until then.
Assessing China in the tradition of
a non-capitalist market economy, sheds a different light on the existing gap
between coasts and interior, and between China and developing countries respectively,
trusting in the redistributive promises of central authorities.
This article is suggesting a
different argument: China is assessed as an outstanding example demonstrating
that the peripheralizing dynamics of contract
manufacture at the low end of commodity chains can turn into the consolidation
of a former periphery into core, initiating technological and sectoral restructuring. One must keep in mind that Chinas
successful catching-up relied on specific conditions and moments, however. On
the one hand, size, heritage and self-assertion are linked to the long and
outstanding centrality of the country, distinguishing China from other emerging
economies of smaller size and historical significance. It even opens the possibility to conceive the Chinese ascent as
part of a hegemonic change, designating China to take over a leading role in a
future (capitalist or non-capitalist) world-economy. On the other hand, global
restructuring continued playing a role, when China’s admission to the World
Trade Organization (2001) and the out-phasing of the World Textile Agreement
(2004) reflected the end of Western protectionism for mature consumer
industries, allowing China to make use of the liberalization to outcompete
smaller developing countries and incorporate them into Chinese-controlled
global commodity chains. Thus, China starts acting as core, if not contributing
to the peripheralization of other developing
countries[80], so
integrating them into a reshaped peripheral relation with a Chinese core.
Peripheralization is equally taking place with regard
to the coastal companies’ initiatives to outsource labor
intensive operations into the Western Chinese provinces. They follow planning
directives, which promote the upgrading of the coastal industries at the expense
of cheap labor relocated to the interior. Core
formation shows a polarizing tendency, contributing to the increase and the
upward mobility of the middle classes in the coastal regions, while relocating
low wages to the internal provinces, hence contributing to their peripheralization. Conversely, official planning documents
refer to the developmental effects, linked with the expansion of growth to
rural areas.
It is of course possible, as Arrighi suggests[81],
conceiving the production networks within China and the neighboring
countries as a revival of the old steering capacity of the Chinese center to intermediate in the East Asian hemisphere,
balancing relations and supporting regional integration for the benefit of all
participants. It is still to be proved however, that the concept of harmony,
expressed in the official documents, can resist the pressures to compete in a
capitalist world-economy, which is not, at least not yet, following Confucian
ideals, but the logic of capital-accumulation.
[1] Griffiths, Rudyard
– Luciani,
Patrick (eds.), Does the 21st
Century Belong to China? Kissinger and Zakaria vs.
Ferguson and Li. The Munk Debate on
China. Toronto: Anasi, 2011).
[2] Henry Kissinger, On China, New
York: Penguin Press, 2011.
[3] Pomeranz, Kenneth, The Great Divergence. China, Europe and the
Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton – Oxford: Princeton
University Press;
Frank, Andre Gunder, Re-Orient. Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley – Los Angeles – London: University of California
Press, 1998; Vanhaute Eric, Cutting the Gordian Knot of World
History: Giovanni Arrighi’s Model of the Great
Divergence and Convergence, in: Journal
of World-Systems Research Vol XVII, No 1, pp. 89-106.
[4] National People’s Congress of the
PR China, 12th Five Years Plan of the
People’s Republic of China (2011-2015), http://www.eu-china.net/upload/pdf/materialien/11-06-30_12th-Five-Year-Plan-China-english.pdfhttp://www.eu-china.net/upload/pdf/materialien/11-06-30_12th-Five-Year-Plan-China-english.pdf
[5] China Institute for Reform and Development (ed.), Giving Priority to Enriching People. Orientation of the Second Round of
Transition and Reform. China Reform Research Report, 2011, Introduction.
[6] China Institute for Reform and
Development, p. 164.
[7] There is a legion of literature,
demonizing China’s threat, hence contributing to establishing a Chinese
hegemonic core as a fait accompli – compare Martin Jacques, When China Rules the World: The End of the
Western World and the Birth of a New Global Order, London-New York: Allen
Lane, 2012; Halper, Stefan, Beijing
Consensus: How China’s Authoritarian Model Will Dominate the 21st Century,
New York: Basic Books, 2011) or Subramanian, Arvind, Eclipse: Living in the Shadow of China’s Ecnomic
Dominance , Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics,
2011.
[8] Frank, Andre Gunder,
Meet Uncle Sam – Without Clothes – Parading Around China and the World, in: Critical Sociology 32 (1), 2006, pp.
17-44; Arrighi, Giovanni, Adam
Smith in Bejing. Lineages of the 21st
Century. London:
Verso, 2007.
[9] Zakaria,
in: Griffiths - Luciani, Does the 21st Century, p. 55.
[10] Zakaria,
Fareed, The Rise of Illiberal Democracy, in: Foreign Affairs, Nov/Dec. 1997, pp. 22-43
[11] Yasheng,
Huang, Capitalism with Chinese Characteristics.
Entrepreneurship and the State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008..
[12] Oreskes, Naomi
and Conway, Erik M., The Collapse of
Western Civilization. A View from the Future. New York: Columbia University
Press, 2014.
[13] Arrighi ,
Adam Smith in Beijing; Frank, Andre Gunder, Meet
Uncle Sam – Without Clothes – Parading Around China and the World, in: Critical Sociology 32 (1), 2006, pp.
17-44; Wallerstein Immanuel, Structural Crisis, or
why capitalists man no longer find capitalism rewarding, in: Wallerstein, Immanuel/Collins Randall/Mann Michael/Derluguan Calhoun, Does
Capitalism have a Future? Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2013, pp. 9-36.
[14] Serious doubts vis-à-vis over-estimating the Chinese miracle were expressed by Nolan, Peter, Is China Buying the World? Malden, MA: Polity Press, 2012 and Krasilshchikov, Victor, The Malaise from Success: The East Asian “Miracle” Revised , Saarbrücken: Lambert Academic Publishing, 2014.
[15] Nolan, Is China buying, pp. 16-20.
[16] Nolan, Is China buying, pp. 22f.,
49f.
[17] The Household Responsibility
System, introduced 1978-1983, was at the origins of „Reform and Opening“. It
enabled peasants to produce and sell to the market. In a first step mobility
restrictions were lifted, allowing peasants to work in nearby towns in collectivly owned “Township and Village Enterprises”
(TVEs)- See Arrighi, Adam Smith in Beijing, p. 362;
Unger, Jonathan, The Transformation of
Rural China. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharp, 2002. They were not able to prevent the migration
of peasant workers to the coastal provinces, however. Lacking „household
registration“ (hukou)
at their new place of work, the workers relied on family support back home,
providing social care, thus compensating for the lack of social security for
migrant workers. See Pun, Ngai, Made in China, Women factory workers in a global workplace. Durham: Duke
University Press, 2005 .
[18] Nolan, Is China buying, p. 59f.
[19] Pun, Made in China; Scherrer Christoph (ed.), China’s Labor Question. München: Rainer Hampp Verlag, 2011.
[20] Komlosy,
Andrea, Vom Nachzügler zum Trendsetter. Chinesische Arbeitswelten im Textil-
und Bekleidungssektor, in: Blätter für
Technikgeschichte 73 ( 2011), pp. 73-104, here 81.
[21] Nolan, Is China buying, p. 55.
[22] China Daily, July 27, 2011.
[23] Nolan, Is China, p. 98.
[24] Neues
Deutschland, February 5, 2014. A further privatization was stopped by the left-wing Greek government beginning
2015.
[25] Nolan, Is China buying, pp. 84-95,
is listing major U.S. and German FDI and acquisitions in China by sector.
[26] In 2013: Volkswagen, General Motors, Hyundai, Toyota, Nissan, PSA-Citroen, Ford, BMW, Mercedes-Benz, Fiat, Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, April 2, 2013.
[27] Reference in Nolan, Is China
buying, p. 11.
[28] This event received broad coverage
in the international media; it is analyzed in great
detail in Arrighi 2007, Adam Smith in Beijing, pp.
280-283 and Nolan, Is China buying, pp. 80-99.
[29] Le Monde, December 7, 2014.
[30] Other Western business and
political groups welcome Chinese investments and partnership for facilitating
entry into the Chinese market – Ibid.
[31] Nolan, Is China buying, pp. 95ff.
[32] Ibid.; China Daily, July 7, 2014.
[33] Nolan, Is China buying, p. 74.
[34] Krasilshchikov, The
Malaise.
[35] According to international classification
textile industry comprises the production of fibres and fabrics, while garment
industry refers to the manufacturing of fabrics into clothes, technical and
home textiles. In the case of knitwear both fabric making and final assembling
are classified as textile industry. Here „textile“ is used for the whole
production line from design to the finished product.
[36] According to Shanghai Museum of
Textiles, run by the Shanghai Textile Holding (Group) Corporation (visited in
August 2011).
[37] Xiaolan, Fu – Yuning, Gao, Export Processing Zones in China: A Survey. Geneva: ILO, 2007. http://ilo.org/public/french/dialogue/download/epzchineenglish.pdf
[38] For the periodization of Chinese
post-opening development policies see Wenten, Frido, Restructured Class-Relations since 1978, in: Scherrer Christoph (ed.), China’s Labor Question. München: Rainer Hampp Verlag, 2011, pp. 28-48..
[39] Alexander, Peter - Chan, Anita, Does China have an Apartheid Pass System?, in: Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies 30/4 (2004), pp. 609-629.
[40] Chan, Anita, China’s Workers under Assault. The Exploitation of Labor
in a Globalizing Economy. Armonk/London: M. E. Sharpe, 2001; Chang, Leslie, Factory Girls. Voices
from the Heart of Modern China. London:
Picador, 2010; Pun, Made in China.
[41] Gereffi, Gary – Memedovic, Olga, The
Global Apparel Value Chain: What Prospects for Upgrading by Developing
Countries? Wien: UNIDO, 2003; also see Komlosy, Andrea, Weltmarkttextilien: Globale
Güterketten im historischen Wandel, in: Fischer Karin/Reiner Christian/Staritz
Cornelia (eds.), Globale Güterketten.
Weltweite Arbeitsteilung und ungleiche Entwicklung. Wien: Promedia, 2010,
pp. 76-97.
[42] Ferenschild, Sabine -
Wick, Ingeborg, Globales Spiel um Kopf und
Kragen. Das Ende des Welttextilabkommens verschärft soziale Spaltungen.
Siegburg-Neuwied: Südwind, 2004, p. 9-16.
[43] China Institute for Reform and Development, Giving Priority; National People’s Congress of the PR China, 12th Five Years Plan 2011-2015.
[44] Labor Contract Law 2007 (effective since 2008); Social Security Law 2010 – see Zhang, Minjie, Urbanization and Migrant Workers in Yiwu, China, in: Van der Linden, Marcel (ed.), Grenzüberschreitende Arbeitergeschichte: Konzepte und Erkundungen/Labour History Beyond Borders: Concepts and Explorations (= ITH 45. Linzer Konferenz). Leipzig: Leipziger Universitätsverlag, 2010, pp. 223-240, here 230f. Minimum wages were mandated by district, county or provincial governments.
[45] Pun, Ngai - Ching, Kwan Lee, Aufbruch der Zweiten Generation. Wanderarbeit, Gender und Klassenzusammensetzung in China. Berlin: Assoziation A, 2010; Egger, Georg – Fuchs, Daniel et. al. (eds.): Arbeitskämpfe in China. Berichte von der Werkbank der Welt. Wien: Promedia, 2013.
[46] The National Human Rights Action
Plan of China for 2009/10 lists 810.000 violations of labor
and social laws. 14.000 arbitration commissions were convened, and more than 2
million mediators active in resolving labor conflicts
– China Daily, July 15, 2011.
[47] In contrast to Original Equipment Manufacture (OEM), ODM includes the whole production line from design to the finished product for a customer-buyer, while OBM designates the production under one’s own label or brand.
[48] National People’s Congress of the
PR China, 12th Five Years Plan of the
People’s Republic of China (2011-2015), ch. 9.
http://www.eu-china.net/upload/pdf/materialien/11-06-30_12th-Five-Year-Plan-China-english.pdf
[49] Ibid., Columne
4, Key fields of manufacturing, Xhinhua News Agency.
[50] According to Yin Xingming, China Institute for Economic Studies, Fudan University, July 25, 2011.
[51] National People’s Congress, 12th Five Years Plan, ch. 10.
[52] China Daily, July 25, 2011.
[53] Komlosy, Andrea, Von der verlängerten Werkbank zum Global Player, China auf dem Weg zu einem Zentrum der Weltwirtschaft, in: Egger Georg - Fuchs Daniel et. al. (eds.), Arbeitskämpfe in China. Berichte von der Werkbank der Welt. Wien: Promedia, 2013, p. 35-52, here p. 50.
[54] Neue Zürcher Zeitung, August 8, 2011.
[55] Jauch,
Herbert – Traub-Mertz, Rudolf (eds.), The Future of the Textile Industry in
Sub-Saharan Africa. Cape Town: Friedrich Ebert Foundation, 2006.
[56] AGOA is a U.S. trade preference
program for Sub-Saharan countries (2000-2015, extended to 2025), allowing
African apparel quota free (until 2004) and duty free entry to the U.S. It is
supposed to foster jobs and income in the local African garment industry. – Gibbon, Peter, The African Growth and Opportunity Act and the
Global Commodity Chain for Clothing, in: World Development vol. 31 (2003), 11, pp. 1809-1827. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0305750X03001487
[57] Bennet,
Mark, Lesotho’s export textiles and garment industry, in: Jauch,
Herbert – Traub-Mertz, Rudolf (eds.), The Future of the Textile Industry in Sub-Saharan
Africa. Cape Town: Friedrich Ebert Foundation, 2006. http://library.fes.de/pdf-files/iez/03796/12lesotho.pdf.
[58] C.E.T.A. service office Shanghai
was founded by Germany, Switzerland, Finland, Austria, France and Spain –
Communication by C.E.T.A. executive Vivian Zhu (July 18, 2011).
[59] E.g. Dragon, Erdos,
Flying, Gujin, Heilan, Hengyoanxiang, Horse Bobu, Lan Tang, Lining, North Tiger, Smart 1933, Three Gun Group,
Youngor, White Collor etc.
– for more see Shanghai Museum of Textiles.
[60] New York Times, September 26, 2013.
[61] According to: Shanghai Museum of
Textiles.
[62] Xiaolan - Yuning, Export Processing Zones, p. 4.
[63] A former factory was transformed
into the Shanghai Textile Museum documenting local textile history and providing
information for the information above.
[64] Jin Yan
(Shanghai), Joachim Debatin (Shanghai) and Stefan Mangold (Haining-Vienna) were
establishing contacts with the companies, helped preparing and accompanied my
visits. I am grateful to the owners and directors of Danfeng
(Haining), Dornier-Chindo
(Shanghai), Dual (Nanjing), Colon (Jiangyin), Jiale und Xishengyu (Jinshan) for welcoming me and providing insights into their
sites and management in July and August 2011. A more detailed report about my
visits is available in: Komlosy, Vom Nachzügler
zum Trendsetter.
[65] Butollo, Florian, The End of Cheap Labour. Industrial
Transformation and “Social Upgrading” in China. Chicago: Chicago University
Press, 2015. Case studies of garment and LED industries reveal that industrial
upgrading, opposite to governments claims, rarely supports qualitative
improvements in working conditions and wages.
[66] Ferguson, in: Griffiths - Luciani,
Does the 21st Century, p. 25f; Frank, Re-Orient; and Menzel, Ulrich, Die Ordnung der Welt. Berlin: Suhrkamp
2015 (forthcoming) support this perspective, pointing on size, heritage and
successful catching up.
[67] For a world-systemic understanding of Kondratiev cycles see Komlosy,
Andrea, Krisen, lange Wellen und die Weltsystemtheorie, in: Friedrich Ebert
Stiftung (ed.), Arbeitnehmerinteressen in
Krisenzeiten. Köln:
Dietz, 2015 forthcoming.
[68] Arrighi,
Adam Smith in Beijing and Wallerstein, Structural
crisis - suggest this interpretation.
[69] Arrighi,
Adam Smith in Beijing, p. 361.
[70] Oreskes –
Convey, the Collapse of Western Civilization.
[71] E.g. the movies Divergent, Elysium,
Showpiercer, The Hunger Games, The Zero Theorem – New
York Times, October 13, 2014.
[72] Rufin, Jean-Christophe, Globalia. Paris, 2004.
[73] Nolan, Peter, Imperial Archipelago,
in: New Left Review 80 (March/April
2013), pp. 77-95.
[74] Pomeranz,
The Great Divergence; Frank, ReOrient; Sugihara, Kaoru (ed.), Japan, China, and the Growth of the Asian International Economy,
1850-1914. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005; Wong, Bin R., China Transformed. Historical Change and the
Limits of European Experience. Ithaca-London: Cornell University Press,
1997.
[75] Ibid., p. 332.
[76] Arrighi, Adam Smith, p. 318; Wong, China Transformed, p. 148; Weigelin-Schwiedrzik, Susanne, Zentrum und Peripherie in China und Ostasien, in: Linhart, Sepp - Weigelin-Schwierdzik, Susanne (eds.), Ostasien 1600 - 1900. Geschichte und Gesellschaft. Wien: Promedia, 2004, pp. 81-98.
[77] e.g. Arrighi, Adam Smith in Beijing, p.7; Minqi, Li , The Rise of China and the Demise of the Capitalist World Economy. Monthly Review Press U.S., 2009.
[78]Scholz, Jochen, Worum es geht. Die Ukraine-Krise und die geopolitische Konstante auf dem eurasischen Kontinent, in: Thoden, Ronald – Schiffer, Sabine (eds.), Ukraine im Visier. Russlands Nachbar als Zielscheibe geostrategischer Interessen. Frankfurt/Main: Selbrund Verlag, 2014, pp. 89-107.
[79] There are as well conservative as
left-wing advocats of the inevitable rise of Chinese
imperialism.
[80] South-Saharan countries had a long
history of colonial rule and degradation to the delivery of slaves or raw
materials to Western colonial powers. After decolonization they made some
progress in state supported establishing of domestic industries. When the debt
crisis of the 1980s brought in International Monetary Organisations requiring
market liberalization and austerity measures, the new industries declined or
collapsed. In the 1990s and 2000s Chinese investors entered a situation, which
was already shaped by re-peripheralization – Traub-Mertz, Rudolf – Jauch,
Herbert, The African textile and clothing industry: From import-substitution to
export orientation, in: Jauch, H. – Traub-Mertz (eds.), The
Future of the Textile Industry in Sub-Saharan Africa. Cape Town: Friedrich
Ebert Foundation, 2006, pp. .9-35. http://library.fes.de/pdf-files/iez/03796/02article.pdf
[81] Arrighi,
Adam Smith in Beijing, p. 347.