Trade and the flag:

integration and conflict in 19th  and

early 20th century deglobalization

 

Chris Chase-Dunn, Anders Carlson, Chris Schmitt, Shoon Lio,

Richard Niemeyer and Robert A. Hanneman

 

Institute for Research on World-Systems

University of California-Riverside, Riverside, CA 92521

 

 

 

To be presented at the Section on Peace, War, and Social Conflict Roundtable, Fri, Aug 11 - 2:30pm - 3:25pm, Annual meeting of the American Sociological Association, Montreal. Draft v.8-9-06; 7470 words

IROWS Working Paper #19 https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows19/irows19.htm


Abstract:

The density and contours of networks of transnational and international economic integration are hypothesized by many theorists to be causally related to the patterns of cooperation and conflict. [1] The usual notion is that trade creates ties of symmetrical interdependence, which are likely to inhibit conflict. We seek to test this hypothesis in the 19th and early 20th century run-up to World War I. We examine the relationship between the structure of conflict and the contours of trade ties during the 19th century wave of globalization and deglobalization.  How were the international trade ties related to the patterns of conflict and alliance that emerged during World War I? Germany was linked by trade, immigration and elite family connections with both Britain and the United States, and yet both World Wars I and II pitted the Germans against Britain and the U.S. But were the trade ties of Germany with its enemies large and significant relative to the total international trade, or were they insignificant elements that had little bearing on the proclivities of nation-states to fight one another? We replicate and improve upon earlier studies that used correlational analysis of nation-state dyads (e.g. Barbieri 2002) and wel also employ formal network analysis to test the earlier finding of a positive relationship between trade ties and enmity. 

 

Waves of Globalization

            Over the past few decades, there has been a surge of interest in the relationship between globalization and political conflict in the interstate system. Most of the theorists of the global capitalism school contend that beginning with the 1960s and 1970s, the world of national economies became transformed into a transnational and global political economy (e.g. Sklair 2001).  Scholars using the world-systems perspective contend that the world-system of capitalism has been importantly transnational for hundreds of years and that globalization in the sense of the expansion and intensification of large-scale intercontinental interaction networks is both an upward trend and a cycle. There were earlier periods of rapid globalization that were followed by periods of deglobalization in which large-scale interactions diminished.  Keynesian national development (the global New Deal) was the predominant strategy of the development project led by the hegemonic United States after World War II. These global policies were designed to regulate the cowboy capitalism of the roaring 1920s, to prevent the reoccurrence of the radical deglobalization that occurred in the 1930s, and to prevent the reoccurrence of the global warfare of the 1940s. The international financial institutions that were set up at the Bretton Woods, New Hampshire conference in 1944 were designed to take the rough edges off of global capitalism by enabling national states to regulate their economies, to encourage good wages, and to develop industrial capacities.  Thus the world of regulated national economies between World War II and the 1980s, to the extent that it really existed, was a product of the global New Deal, however watered down from its original vision. It is the comparison of this “development project” image of national economies with the “globalization project” image of the post-1980s world that gives the global capitalism school its boost.

            Neoliberalism was the political ideology that became hegemonic in the 1980s because the competing core countries - Japan and Germany - caught up with the U.S. in the most profitable mass consumption industries in the 1970s, and the long-term tendency for labor costs and taxes to rise resulted in a crisis of overaccumulation. The profit rate in production and trade declined in the most profitable sectors, and so capital and its organic intellectuals responded by attacking labor unions and the welfare state.[2] The market was glorified and the state was depicted as a vampire of taxation. Privatization, deregulation, down-sizing, streamlining, cutting entitlements and outsourcing became the order of the day, and these policies spread from their points of origin in the United States and Britain to the rest of the world. This political ideology used the new cheap information, communications and transportation technologies to globalize markets for trade and investment and to pit poor workers in the periphery against better-paid workers in the core.

            Yet, in contrast to the global capitalism school, we argue that the old system of national states still exists and that something like the current wave of globalization had happened before during the decline of British hegemony in the late 19th  and early 20th century. Studies of trade globalization – the ratio of international trade to the world GDP--  show that there was a high peak in the 1880s, then a decline until 1900, then another small rise, and a crash in 1929, and then a rise after World War II to the present, which is somewhat higher than the peak in 1880, but not extremely higher (see Figure 1). Investment globalization probably followed a similar trajectory (Chase-Dunn, et al 2002)

Figure 1: Waves of trade globalization (Chase-Dunn, Kawano and Brewer 2000)

 

Global Elite Networks and International Trade Links

            This paper is part of a larger project, the purpose of which is to study the contours of global elite and international integration since 1840 and to study the relationship between these contours of connection and the patterns of conflict that emerged over the same time period.  There have been a significant number of theoretical and empirical works by political scientists and sociologists that examine the effects of economic interdependence and international conflict (McMillan 1997; Barbieri and Schneider 1999; Barbieri 2002; Rosecrance and Thompson 2003; Maoz 2004, Maoz et al 2006, forthcoming). Various liberal theories of globalization argue that economic integration should decrease international conflict. [3]We observe that these approaches should distinguish between horizontal connections (of equality) and vertical connections (power-dependency relations). The latter may be quite likely to produce conflict (Barbieri 2002; Rosecrance and Thompson 2003).

            Contra these perspectives, many observers have noted that interdependent connections have not served to prevent major conflicts in the modern international system (Thompson and Tucker 1997; Rosecrance and Thompson 2003). Both Britain and the United States had major connections with Germany before the outbreaks of World Wars I and II.  We want to study the whole global network so that we can see how these known ties compare with the connections between other actors. It may be that the international network ties of Germany and Turkey (allies in World War I) were significantly stronger than those among the countries that they ended up fighting. And it may be that indirect ties that can only be ascertained by formal analysis of the whole network will reveal contours that can account for the emergence of conflict.  Only a study of the international network can allow us to see whether the links that crosscut conflict chasms were small or large relative to the other links in the network.[4]

            Our larger project consists of two parts. In the first we are using a world historical perspective to examine the links between elite individuals, families and organizations within each country with those same actors in other countries. This involves a close reading of the histories of each country with attention to connections with other countries (see Reifer and Chase-Dunn 2003; Barr et al 2006). The second part of our project (discussed here) uses quantitative data on the interactions among nation-states to trace the changing patterns of network connections since 1880.  This enables us to use the national network patterns to place the information from our studies of elites in a world historical context, and to study the congruence or lack thereof, between different kinds of international connections. We also intend to examine the relationships between international network structures and the patterns of conflictive relations that were so evident in the first half of the twentieth century. We know that the international system bifurcated into Allies and Axis states in the World Wars. Were these conflict-alliance bloc structures related to the trade network? Did the network of global trade become more factional in the years prior to the outbreak of world war? And did these factions correspond with the emergent conflict factions?

            We also will eventually use network data to compare the overall magnitude of global integration in the nineteenth century with the magnitude and forms of integration that have emerged since World War II.[5] The question of global magnitudes is important because many students of globalization have assumed that the high degree of contemporary integration of the global capitalist class will prevent the emergence of future interimperial rivalry and war among core states. But if there was a similarly high level of global elite integration in the late nineteenth century this assumption may be brought into question.

            In this paper we analyze mainly international trade relations, but international financial links are another important dimension of global economic networks that we plan to empirically examine in the future. Imports and exports of goods and services are much easier to get comparable information on than flows of investment, especially for the nineteenth century. Ideally we would like to differentiate trade flows into goods that are more strategic and profitable vs. those that are less so. But that is not possible on a sufficient scale for the nineteenth century.

 

Transnational Relations and State-centrism

            The use of data on nation-states is defensible on both theoretical and practical grounds, and should not expose us to the slings and barbs of those who would accuse us of state-centrism. Firstly, national states have been, and still are, important organizations within the world-system. Transnationalism has not just arisen since 1980. There have been waves of transnationalism and waves of nationalism since the chartered companies of the seventeenth century organized production and distribution on a global scale.  The contemporary transnational corporations undoubtedly organize a greater portion of the total world economy than the 17th century chartered companies did. But then and now, national states were and remain important players on the global stage.

            We may say this without denying the perspective developed by William I. Robinson (2004) and others on the emergence of a transnational capitalist state that reconfigures existing national states (and international organizations) as its instruments. Indeed, we see the emergence of a transnational state, not just in the period since the 1980s, but since the Concert of Europe that was Britain’s effort to prevent further French revolutions and Napoleonic escapades.  The Concert of Europe, the League of Nations and the United Nations have been the first steps toward global state formation, but the top of the stairway to a true world state remains in the distant future. We agree with Robinson that it is important to theorize the transnational state and to study its emergence (see Chase-Dunn1990;2005). None of this prevents us from studying existing national states, and for using data on national states and international trade to study world-system patterns.

            The practical reason for using data on national states is that they are the only data that are available for most of the regions of the system over the time period that we seek to study.  As with all secondary data analyses, we need to be chary about the ways in which the structuring of the data by its original providers may distort our results.

 

Methods for Our Analysis       

            We adopt the generalized strategy of measurement error modeling that is part of the structural equations tradition. This means that instead of trying to pick the best single empirical indicator of an underlying concept or variable, we want to use several proxy indicators and to model the relationships among the proxies as well as using them to estimate the true underlying values of the variables. In practice we may not have enough data to be able to actually employ the techniques of structural equations modeling of measurement error. But we shall use the generalized logic of gathering multiple proxy indicators whenever this is possible.

            Because the data are less complete in the early decades, we have a growing population of nodes as we get closer to the present. This, and the actual changes that occurred in country boundaries over the period studied (e.g. the break-up of the Ottoman and Austro-Hungarian empires, etc.), mean that we have a changing set of nodes in the network. This makes it difficult to know whether observed changes were due to real changes in the pattern of trade ties or to the inclusion of nodes that were formerly not included because of missing data. One approach to this problem that we have used in earlier research is to study constant groups over time. If we find similar trends between the constant groups and the networks that are adding (or deleting) nodes we can infer that observed changes are not due to changes in the compared units.

 

Variable Construction

Trade Network Data

            Much of the late 19th century and early 20th century trade data are reported in the country’s domestic currency, which makes cross-national comparison impossible.  There are several possible ways to deal with this problem. One is to convert all the country currency values into a single currency such as the pound sterling or the U.S. dollar using currency market exchange rates.[6] There are a number of known problems with this approach.  Currency market exchange rates are set by the competitive buying and selling of currencies during some periods, but in other periods the exchange rates have been set by international agreements. Between the Bretton Woods conference in 1944 and the early 1970s the U.S. dollar was pegged to a fictitious gold standard, and other currencies were pegged to the dollar. These regulated exchange rates can still be used to change country currencies into dollars, but this conversion reflects a worldwide agreement to regulate currency markets rather than a world market for money. In 1974 the dollar and other currencies were freed to exchange in world money markets.

            Another problem is that market exchange rates reflect the activities of large currency traders, rather than just the daily conversions of currencies carried out by people who need to change money. The actions of currency traders are intended to make profits by buying and selling money, and this activity does not necessarily reflect the value of the goods and services that national economies produce. This is why economists have tried to devise a better method for converting currencies into a single comparable metric that is based on purchasing power in different countries (Kravis Heston and Summers 1982). These so-called purchasing power parity (PPP) conversion ratios are not available for the 19th century and the whole approach has been savaged by critics (e.g. Korzeniewicz, Stach and Patil 2004).

            Another method of making country currency values comparable is to compute a percentage using a denominator in the same metric units (country currencies).  We have the total value of exports and imports for each country in country currency, so we could compute the percentage of the country’s trade with a particular other trade partner.  This puts the numbers into a comparable metric: percentages. But this is not a good solution to the problem for our purposes. It does eliminate the need to use exchange rates, but at the cost of computing a variable that will not be useful for our purpose of examining the relative importance of a particular trade link in the context of the larger world trade network.   Knowing that the imports of Germany from Britain were x% of Germany’s total imports does not tell us how important this was in world trade. Ideally we would like to know the ratio of the value of the imports to the size of the world economy as a whole, or to the total value of international trade (but see below). To compute these percentages we would need to have the relevant denominator values in the currency of the country, and these we do not have.  So we will need to use exchange rates to convert the country currency values into a common comparable metric. Most of the Barbieri (2000) trade data used in our analysis was converted to current US dollars using exchange rates taken from the Polity II project (Gurr, Jaggers, and Moore1989). 

(did we use imports, exports, both or what?)

Construction of Conflict Dyads

            The countries considered in this analysis are those that fought in World War I, those core countries of Western Europe that remained neutral, and the three largest, non-combatant, semiperiphery countries.  Specifically these include the Allied and Central Powers, Sweden, Switzerland, Denmark, and the Netherlands, as well as China, Mexico and Brazil. 

            To quantify the intensity of conflict between two states (dyads), we relied upon three separate indicators: 1) the Correlates of War data set compiled by Singer and Small measuring the number of battle deaths experienced by each country in the WWI, and 2) the Barbieri conflict data set consisting of two ordinal measures of conflict during WWI: one representing the level of aggression country A displayed towards country B, and the other representing the level of aggression country B displayed towards country A.  Interestingly, each of these data sets exhibited complimentary weaknesses.  The Correlates of War data is useful after a country goes to war because it demonstrates how “intensely” the country was committed to fighting as a function of the number of its dead, but the data says nothing of the level of conflict between countries before they go to war.  In a similar fashion, the Barbieri data does an excellent job of demonstrating the “ramping up” processes leading up to WW1, but after the fact it is useless in distinguishing various levels of commitment to the war once it has begun.  Further, both data sets in isolation demonstrated very high skewness and kurtosis, making interpretation of correlation coefficients problematic. 

            To remedy both of these problems we constructed a standardized index of conflict intensity that combined all three measures.  This was carried out by transforming the “raw” values of each data set into standardized scores using SPSS, and summing the result.  At this point we realized that by constructing the index in this fashion, we had inadvertently reduced the contribution of the Correlates of War data.  What was once a very large difference in intensity between “a militarized shared border,” and, “a combined war dead of over one million soldiers,” had now been reduced to a one or two point index difference.  Also, one country’s decision to enter into the war as an ally of another is an indicator level of (low) conflict intensity that was not being taken into account. So we modified our conflict indicator by doubling the weight of the contribution of the battle deaths, and also coding for whether or not a state was an ally of another. 

            So as to make neutrality during WWI represent zero conflict between a pair of states, the index was scaled so that a value of –3.16 equated to war ally, 0 equated to neutral and a value of 16 equated to the highest level of conflict intensity.  We do not have a measure that takes into account various degrees of “war ally,” so the index jumps from –3.14 to 0, and then ramps up incrementally to more than 16.  It should also be noted that although this final measure of conflict does still display minor skewness and kurtosis, it is by far the best in this regard when compared to the Correlates of War and Barbieri indicators (see Table 1).     

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

N

Minimum

Maximum

Mean

Std. Deviation

Skewness

Kurtosis

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Level of Conflict

552

-3.14

16.09

.6315

3.14

2.023

4.8

COW Battle Deaths

552

0

3500000

208681.88

602579.10

3.143

9.584

Barbieri Conflict Measure

552

0

20

1.04

3.998

3.747

12.386

Table 1. Descriptive Statistics for our constructed conflict indicator (level of conflict), the original COW battle death data, and the Barbieri conflict data. (Notice the significant reduction in both skewness and kurtosis.)

 

Dyadic Correlations between Conflict and Trade in 1880-1913

            After constructing the conflict index, a Pearson r test was used to determine the correlation between levels of trade for eight time periods leading up to World War I and the intensity of conflict between combatants during the war.  The results are shown in Table 2:   

 

 

Intensity of Conflict

Amount of Trade 1913

2-tailed Significance

.231

.000***

Amount of Trade 1912

2-tailed Significance

.232

.000***

Amount of Trade 1911

2-tailed Significance

.233

.000***

Amount of Trade 1910

2-tailed Significance

.235

.000***

Amount of Trade 1905

2-tailed Significance

.173

.000***

Amount of Trade 1900

2-tailed Significance

.103

.016*

Amount of Trade 1895

2-tailed Significance

.110**

.010

Amount of Trade 1890

2-tailed Significance

.101*

.017

Amount of Trade 1885

2-tailed Significance

.088*

.040

Amount of Trade 1880

2-tailed Significance

.044

.299

*** Significant at .001 level

**   Significant at .01 level

*     Significant at .05 level

Table 2: Dyadic Correlations between Conflict and Trade in 1880-1913

 

            As indicated by the table, the amount of imports one country received from another had a significant positive correlation with the level of conflict experienced within the dyad during WWI.  This was the case in each of the above years, except 1880, which was also positive.

 

 Controlling for Size: Partial Correlation between Trade and Conflict

            Given that a portion of the intensity of conflict index is measured in battle deaths, it is advisable to control for the size of the population of the countries involved.  Population dyads were created as a control variable using 1913 population data compiled by the Correlates of War Project and the Eugene software database.  The 1913 data were used because we are interested specifically in WWI.  While population obviously grew at different rates in different countries between the years of 1880 (our earliest period) and 1913, we do not believe that differential growth occurred at a rate substantial enough to affect the outcome of our analysis.  Table 3 depicts the results of the partial correlation between the amount of trade leading up to World War I and the level of intensity of conflict, controlling for total population:

 

Partial Correlation

Controlling for Population

 

Intensity of Conflict

Amount of Trade 1913

2-tailed Significance

.2289

.000***

Amount of Trade 1912

2-tailed Significance

.2302

.000***

Amount of Trade 1911

2-tailed Significance

.2304

.000***

Amount of Trade 1910

2-tailed Significance

.2327

.000***

Amount of Trade 1905

2-tailed Significance

.1703

.000***

Amount of Trade 1900

2-tailed Significance

.1012

.018*

Amount of Trade 1895

2-tailed Significance

.1081

.011

Amount of Trade 1890

2-tailed Significance

.0994*

.020

Amount of Trade 1885

2-tailed Significance

.0864**

.043

Amount of Trade 1880

2-tailed Significance

.0425

.319

*** Significant at .001 level

**   Significant at .01 level

*     Significant at .05 level

 

Table 3: Dyadic Correlations between Conflict and Trade in 1880-1913 controlling for population size

 

            Although controlling for population size reduced the strength of the positive correlation between level of trade and conflict by small amount, the relationship once again remains significant in all years except 1880. Thus our new analysis of dyadic correlations using an improved measure of conflict confirms earlier results by Barbieri (2002) that show a significant positive relationship between trade connections and the emergence of conflict. But does this relationship hold up when we examine the whole network of interaction. Analysis of dyads cannot take account of indirect connections but formal network analysis can examine the structure of the whole system and look for cliques or factions in the system. Are there strong subgroups in the trade structure and, if so, do these correspond with the conflict factions that emerged in World War I?

 

Network Analysis of Trade and Conflict

          We used UCINet to produce comparable square matrices of our conflict and trade datasets for purposes of formal network analysis. A square matrix is produced by UCINet for purposes of formal network analysis. Network analysis is superior to dyadic correlation analysis because it allows the whole structure of a network to be analyzed including all the direct and indirect links and non-links. This makes it possible to identify cliques or factions within a network and to examine the centrality or peripherality of network nodes. The nodes in this analysis are countries.

            The conflict matrix contains the values for each pair of countries computed for our level of conflict indicator described above. This is then used to produce Figure 2 by means of specifying a cutting point in the distribution of dyad values. For Figure 2 we used ________________________________.

 

Figure 2: Level of Conflict Network for World War I.  (Country names are Correlates of War abbreviations.)

Compare Figure 2 with the list of the blocks in World War I in Table 4.

Allies (Entente)

Central Powers

Neutrals

 

 

 

Belgium

Austria-Hungary

Brazil

France

Bulgaria

China

Greece

Germany

Denmark

Italy

Turkey

Mexico

Japan

 

Netherlands

Portugal

 

Norway

Romania

 

Spain

Russia

 

Sweden

UK

 

Switzerland

USA

 

 

Balkans (YUG)

 

 

Table 4: Conflict Blocs in World War I

            The Central Powers in the middle of Figure 2 are not linked by conflict ties with one another (except for something between Bulgaria and Turkey?). They are surrounded by Entente powers and out on the edges are the neutrals.

(insert the graphic of trade network in 1880 here and compare it with the next figure)

            Figure 3 shows the network structure of trade in 1913 just before the outbreak of World War I. The cutting point we used for the trade network graphic is ______________.

Figure 3 Trade Network for 1913.  (Country names are the Correlates of War abbreviation.)

           

            The trade network graphic uses the values for dyads that we used in our correlational analysis above. We have trade networks every five years from 1880 to 1913. This is a dense network but it clearly has a multicentered core and a periphery.

 

Multiplicative Coreness

            The interaction matrices were also used to calculate multiplicative coreness. A multiplicative core is characterized as a set of nodes possessing a high density of connections amongst themselves, while the multiplicative periphery is characterized as possessing few interconnections.  The consequence of such a structural condition is that nodes located within the core are often capable of greater coordinated action and a greater mobilization of resources, while nodes in the periphery are not. Computed a coreness score for each country using the trade matrices for every five years between 1880 and 1913 and then used these score to compute a gini coefficient that indicates how much dispersion there is in the distribution of coreness scores across countries.

Figure 4 Graph of the relationship between the Gini Coefficient and Level of Network Density for the Trade Network from 1880 to 1913

            Figure 4 is the graph demonstrating the relationship between the Gini Coefficient and the Level of Network Density for the Trade Network of participants in World War 1.  In network analysis, Gini Coefficient measures the amount of inequality between the core and periphery nodes in terms of the distribution of connections. (What is network density?)  Within the trade network presented here the level of inequality as indicated by the Gini Coefficient declines slightly from 1880 to 1910 and then it declines steeply. This indicates that the network is becoming less centralized as British hegemony in the world economy is declining because other countries are growing.  From 1880 to 1910 the core of the network consists solely of the United Kingdom, but in 1910 it expands to include the United Kingdom, the United States, France, Germany, and the Netherlands (representing the current hegemon, the future hegemon, the past hegemonic challenger, the current hegemonic challenger, and the past hegemon respectively).

            At the same time the Gini Coefficient is decreasing, the density of the network is increasing.  In other words, the centralization of control over trade in the world-system is decreasing at the same time the level of competition for trade is increasing. Thus at the level of the global economy, a clear increase in the level of competition and distribution of resources preceded the world war, and these changes accelerated in the years just before the outbreak of the war.  [7]

 

Table 5:  QAP correlations between the level of trade between nodes in the network and the level of conflict occurring during World War 1

 

            We used the QAP routine in UCINet to produce Pearson’s r correlation coefficients for the values in the square conflict and trade matrices. QAP assesses the frequency of random correlations as large as those actually observed, making it possible to test the statistical significance of the observed correlations between two square matrices despite the fact that the cells are not independent from one another.

            As was the case in the dyadic analysis, there is a clear non-negative correlation between trade and conflict.  In other words, the more the nodes of the network trade with each other, the more likely they are to go to war.  Unlike the dyadic analysis though, only the levels of trade in 1913 and 1910 are significant predictors of the level of conflict in World War 1.  Interestingly, the size of the positive correlations is the same for both the dyadic and network analysis.  

            We used UCINet’s Faction routine to identify trade factions from the trade network matrix. The Faction routine allows valued data but requires specification of the number of factions. When three factions are specified UCINet groups the countries as shown in Table 6 based on the trade network data. Table 6 also shows which countries are in which conflict bloc.

 

 

 

Entente Allies

Central Powers

Neutral

 

 

 

Belgium 2

Austria-Hungary 2

Brazil 1

France 2

Bulgaria 2

China 3

Greece 2

Germany 1

Denmark 1

Italy 3

Turkey 2

Mexico 3

Japan 3

 

Netherlands 1

Portugal 1

 

Norway 1

Romania 2

 

Spain 1

Russia 2

 

Sweden 1

UK 2

 

Switzerland 1

USA 3

 

 

Balkans 2

 

 

Table 6: War Factions and Trade Faction (1,2, and 3)

Table 7 below  is a crosstabulation of the conflict blocs and the trade factions.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

War faction

 

 

Total

 

 

Entente Allies

Central Powers

Neutrals

 

 

Trade faction #1

1

1

7

9

 

Trade faction #2

7

3

 

10

 

Trade faction #3

3

 

2

5

Total

 

11

4

9

24

Table 7: Crosstabulation of trade faction by war faction

            For the Entente Allies 7 of 11 are in trade faction #2. For the Central Powers 3 of 4 are also in trade faction #2. For the Nuetrals 7 of 9 are in trade faction #1.  None of the Central Powers are in trade faction #3, which contains 3 Entente Allies and 2 Neutrals.
            So there is not a great match between the trade factions and the conflict blocs. Trade faction #2 contains 75% of the Central Powers and 64% of the Allies.  The best match is that 7 of 9 Neutrals are in trade faction #1.  It would seem logical according to the liberal hypothesis that a country would remain neutral if it was trading with both sides and did not want to offend either one. But instead Tables 6 and 7 show that those countries that were less connected with either side by trade were more likely to remain nuetral. And Germany is in the #1 trade faction with the neutrals. [8]

            Thus the results of network analysis do not contradict earlier findings or the replicated (and improved) dyad analysis described above. Indeed there is some additional positive support for the notion that trade connections do not reduce the likelihood of conflict. But a new connection between trade and conflict is shown in Figure 4 above. The overall shape of the trade network was changing in the decades prior to the war and these changes accelerated just before the war. The network was getting denser and less hierarchical. The centrality of Great Britain was declining. There were more competitors in the center and more connections in the whole network. Figure 1 (on p. 3) shows the trends in overall trade globalization in these same years. Trade globalization is the ratio of the total amount of international trade to the size of the whole world economy (global GDP). What Figure 1 shows is that even though international trade had been growing rapidly in the last decades of the 19th century the whole world economy had been growing even more rapidly, resulting in a decline in trade globalization that bottomed in 1900 and then began a recovery. So the trends of less centralized and denser international trade were occurring in context of decreasing globalization.

            The lack of correspondence that we find between trading factions and the conflict blocs that emerged in the Great War echos what many war historians have often said – the structure of alliances were fluid and did not gell until just before the conflagration. As late as 1901, during the second Boer War, the populations of both Britain and France were gripped with fear that war might break out between these erstwhile allies.

                                               

References

 

Alderson, Arthur S. and Jason Beckfiled 2004 “Power and position in the world city system,”

American Journal of Sociology 109:811-51.

 

Arrighi, Giovanni 1994 The Long Twentieth Century. New York: Verso

 

Bairoch, Paul and Richard Kozul-Wright 1998 “Globalization myths: some historical

reflections on integration, industrialization and growth in the world economy,”

pp. 37-68 in Richard Kozul-Wright and Robert Rowthorn (eds.) Transnational

Corporations and the Global Economy. London: MacMillan

 

Barbieri, Katherine 2002 The Liberal Illusion:  Does Trade Promote Peace? Ann Arbor:  University of Michigan Press.

 

Barr, Kenneth, Shoon Lio, Christopher Schmitt, Anders Carlson, Kirk Lawrence, Jonathan

            Krause, Yvonne Hsu, Christopher Chase-Dunn and Thomas E. Reifer 2006 “Global

            conflict and elite integration in the 19th and early 20th centuries” Presented at the

            Annual Meeting of the American Sociological Association, in Montréal, Canada,

            at 10:30 am on August 11, 2006 at the session on World Systems organized by

            Farshad Araghi. IROWS Working Paper #27 available at        https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows27/irows27.htm

 

Bollen, Kenneth A. 1989 Structural Equations with Latent Variables. New York: John Wiley.

 Bornschier, Volker and Christopher Chase-Dunn (eds.) 1999 The Future of Global Conflict 

            London: Sage.

Carroll, William K. Forthcoming “Global cities in the global corporate network” American

            Journal of Sociology.

Carroll, William K. and Colin Carson 2003 “The Network of Global Corporations and

            Policy Groups: A Structure for Transnational Capitalist Class Formation?” Global

            Networks  3 (1): 29-57.

Chase-Dunn, Christopher 1990 “World State Formation: Historical Processes and Emergent 
               Necessity” Political Geography Quarterly, 9,2: 108-30 (April).               https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows1.txt

Chase-Dunn, Christopher 2005 “Upward sweeps in the historical evolution of world-

            systems” IROWS Working Paper #20 available at

            https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows20/irows20.htm

 

Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Yukio Kawano and Benjamin Brewer 2000 "Trade Globalization since 1795: waves of integration in the world-system," American Sociological Review 65:77-95 (February).   summarized in Scientific American June 2003.

 

Chase-Dunn, Christopher,  Andrew Jorgenson, Rebecca Giem, Shoon Lio, Thomas E. Reifer and John Rogers, 2002 “Waves of Structural Globalization since 1800: New results on Investment Globalization”  A paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Sociological Association, August 16-19, Chicago.

 

Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Andrew Jorgenson,  Shoon Lio and Thomas Reifer, 2005

"The Trajectory of the United States in the World-System: A Quantitative Reflection"  Sociological Perspectives.

 

Choucri, Nazli and Robert North 19xx Nations In Conflict.

 

Eugene Date Management Software: www.eugenesoftware.org

 

Freeman, Linton C., Douglas R. White and A. Kimball Romney 1992 Research Methods in Social Network Analysis. Transaction Press

 

Goldfrank, Walter L. 1977 “Who rules the world: class formation at the international level” Quarterly Journal of Ideology 1,2:32-7.

 

____________1983 “The limits of an analogy: hegemonic decline in Great Britain and

 the United States.” Pp. 143-54 in Albert Bergesen (ed.) Crises and the World-System

Beverly Hills: Sage.

 

Hanneman, Robert nd Introduction to Social Network Methods

http://faculty.ucr.edu/%7Ehanneman/SOC157/TEXT/TextIndex.html

 

Held, David, Anthony McGrew, David Goldblatt and Jonathan Perraton. 1999. Global Transformations: 

Politics, Economics and Culture. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

 

Hirschman, Albert O. 1980 [1945] National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade. Berkeley: University of California Press.

 

Johnson, Ian 2000 “A step-by-step guide to setting up a TimeMap dataset.” Archaeological

Computing Laboratory. University of Sydney.

 

Junne, Gerd 1999 “Global cooperation or rival trade blocs?” in Volker Bornschier and Christopher Chase-Dunn (eds.)

 The Future of Global Conflict. London: Sage

.

Kentor, Jeffrey. 2000a. “Shifting Patterns of Organizational Control in the World-Economy 1800 1990.”

Funded Grant Proposal to World Society Foundation: Zurich, Switzerland.

 

_____. 2000b. Capital and Coercion: The Economic and Military Processes That Have Shaped the World Economy 1800-1990. New York: Garland Publishing.

 

Kentor, Jeffery and Yong Suk Jang 2004 “Yes, there is a transnational business community.” International Sociology 19,3:352-368.

 

Korzeniewicz, Roberto Patricio, Angela Stach and Vrushali Patil 2004 “Measruing national income: a critical assessment.”

Comparative Studies in Society and History

 

Krasner, Stephen D. 1976 “State power and the structure of international trade,” World Politics 28,3:317-47.

 

Kravis, Irving B., Alan Heston and Robert Summers 1982 World Product and Income:

International Comparisons of Real Gross Product. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins

University Press.

 

Krempel, Lothar and  Thomas Pluemper 1999 “International division of labor and global economic processes:

an analysis of the international trade in automobiles” Journal of World-Systems Research, 5,3:487-498

 

Levy, Jack S. 1983 War in the Modern Great Power System, 1495-1975. Lexington:

University Press of Kentucky.

 

Maddison, Angus 1995 Monitoring the World Economy, 1820-1992. Paris: Organization for

Economic Cooperation and Development.

 

_________ 2001 The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Paris: Organization of Economic

Cooperation and Development

 

Mitchell, B.R. 1992 International Historical Statistics: Europe 1750-1988. 3rd ed. New

York: Stockton

 

____________ 1993 International Historical Statistics: The Americas 1750-1988. 2nd ed.

NY:Stockton

 

____________ 1995 International Historical Statistics: Africa, Asia, & Oceania 1750-1988.

2nd ed. NY:Stockton

 

Maoz, Zeev 2006. “Network Polarization, Network Interdependence, and International 
               Conflict, 1816-2002.” Journal of Peace Research, 43(4): 391-411          
http://jpr.sagepub.com/cgi/reprint/43/4/391
 
Maoz, Zeev,  R. Kuperman, L. Terris, and I.  Talmud.  2004 “International Relations: A 
               Network Approach." in New Directions for International Relations, Edited by A.
               Mintz and B. Russett. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books, (with Z. Maoz. R. 
               Kuperman, and L. Terris). http://soc.haifa.ac.il/~talmud/evolution.pdf
 
Maoz, Zeev, R. Kuperman, L. Terris, and I.  Talmud. forthcoming "Structural Equivalence 
               and International Conflict, 1816-2000: A Social Networks Analysis of Dyadic 
               Affinities and Conflict."  Journal of Conflict Resolution 
               http://soc.haifa.ac.il/~talmud/strucequiv.pdf
 
Maoz, Zeev, R. Kuperman, L. Terris, and I.  Talmud. forthcoming "The Enemy of my 
               Enemy: The Effects of Indirect Enmity Relations on Direct Dyadic Relations,"  
                Journal of Politics . 

O’Rourke, Kevin H and Jeffrey G. Williamson 1999 Globalization and History: The Evolution of

            a 19th Century Atlantic Economy. Cambridge, MA.: MIT Press.

 

Polanyi, Karl 2001 [1944] The Great Transformation. Boston: Beacon Press.

Rasler, Karen A. and William Thompson. 1994. The Great Powers and Global Struggle: 1490 1990. Lexington: University Press of Kentucky.

 

Reifer, Thomas E. 2002 “Globalization & the National Security State Corporate Complex (NSSCC) in the Long Twentieth Century,”

 Greenwood Press, The Modern/Colonial Capitalist World-System in the 20th Century, Ramon Grosfoguel and Margarita Rodriguez, eds., Westport, CTGreenwood Press.

 

Reifer, Thomas E. and Christopher Chase-Dunn 2003 “The Social Foundations of Global Conflict and Cooperation: 

Waves of Globalization and Global Elite Integration, 19th to 21st Century. Research Proposal Funded by the National

Science Foundation’s Sociology Program. https://irows.ucr.edu/research/glbelite/globeliteprop03.htm

 

Reifer, Thomas E. “Globalization, Democratization & Global Elite Formation in Hegemonic Cycles:  A Geopolitical Economy,”

2005, in Jonathan Friedman & Christopher Chase-Dunn, eds., Hegemonic Declines, forthcoming Paradigm Publishers, Ch. 7, pp. 183-201.

   

Robinson, William I. 2004 A Theory of Global Capitalism. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

 

Rosecrance, R. 1963. Action and Reaction in World Politics. Boston:  Little Brown.

 

Rosecrance, Richard and Peter Thompson 2003 “Trade, foreign investment and security,” Annual Review of Political Science 6:377-98.

 

Sklair, Leslie. 2001. The Transnational Capitalist Class. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers.

 

Smith, David A. and Douglas R. White 1992 “Structure and Dynamics of the Global

Economy: Network Analysis of International Trade 1965-1980,” Social Forces 70:857-

894

 

Sassen, Saskia 2001 The Global City: New York, London, Tokyo. Princeton: Princeton University

Press.

 

Sklair, Leslie 2001 The Transnational Capitalist Class. Cambridge, MA.: Blackwell.

 

Smith, David A. and Michael Timberlake. 2001. “World City Networks and Hierarchies,

1977-1997: An Empirical Analysis of Global Air Travel Links.” American Behavioral

Scientist 44, 10: 1656-1678.

 

Snyder, Jack 1991. Myths of Empire:  Domestic Politics and International Ambition. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

 

_____. 2000. From Voting to Violence:  Democratization and Nationalist Conflict. New York: W.W. Norton and Co.

 

_____.2003."Imperial Temptations." The National Interest. 71:29-40.

 

Su, Tieting. 1995. "Changes in World Trade Networks: 1938, 1960, 1990" Review XVIII, 3

:431-459 (Summer)

 

Taylor, Peter J 2004 World City Network. London: Routledge.

 

Van der Pijl, Kees. 1984. The Making of an Atlantic Ruling Class. London: Verso.

 

______________ 1998 Transnational Classes and International Relations, New York:  Routledge. 

 

Weber, Max. 1961. General Economic History, New York:  Collier Books.

 

Appendix

 

Histogram for Level of Conflict Index

 

 

Supplementary Trade Data

 

            According to Barbieri (2003), “The Statesman’s Yearbook contains country profiles that usually include tables of foreign trade figures.  When these tables are not present, information was pieced together by reading entries related to a particular state’s economic activities.  For the period 1873-1885 U.S. Congressional records proved to be a useful source of trade data, in particular U.S. Congress (House) Miscellaneous Documents (1887), “Abstract of the Foreign Commerce of Europe, Australia, Asia and Africa, 1873-1885,” United States Consular Reports, No. 85, October. (Washington: Government Printing Office).  Data for this period were supplemented with other sources, including the Statesman’s Yearbook; Mitchell (1982) International Historical Statistics for Africa and Asia (New York: New York University Press); Mitchell (1983) International Historical Statistics for the Americas and Australasia (Detroit, MI: Gale Research Company); and Wattenberg (1976) Introduction and User’s Guide to The Statistical History of the United States from Colonial Times to the Present (New York: Basic Books).  For the period 1912-1913, the primary source used was the League of Nations (1912-1945) annual publications of International Trade Statistics, (Geneva: League of Nations).”

 

            According to Barbieri (2003), “several problems arose when converting trade figures from local currencies to US dollars.  The primary problem was the lack of available exchange rates for many states.  In many instances trade data reports were available, but exchange rates were unavailable.  In addition, Polity II contains a variable that lists the name of the national currency to which the exchange rate is presumed to correspond.  However, in many instances no currency name is given.  Also, in some instances, particularly in Latin American states, the value of import and export flows are reported in two different currencies.  For example, silver pesos may be used for imports, while gold pesos are used for exports.  This requires separate exchange rates for converting imports and exports into US dollar values (see Appendix for supplementary data sources).”

 

Links to Related Data Online

 

Conflict Data Sets: http://www.pcr.uu.se/pdf/conflictdataset2.pdf

http://www.umich.edu/~cowproj/dataset.html
(Link to Correlates of War Project; includes a number of datasets that deal with war/conflict)

Katherine Barbieri Trade Data Sets:

http://sitemason.vanderbilt.edu/site/k5vj7G/new_page_builder_4

http://weber.ucsd.edu/~kgledits/Polity.html
(Link to POLITY project datasets, which include data on cross-national authority structures)



[1] This is part of a larger study of global integration and conflict that uses both quantitative analysis of international patterns and a historical sociology of transnational elite ties. The research proposal for our project is at https://irows.ucr.edu/research/glbelite/globelite.htm and a related paper is at https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows27/irows27.htm

[2] The politicians took pages from the anti-statist ideology and tactics of the New Left in the world revolution of 1968.

[3] The Democratic Peace hypothesis is a major theoretical framework that makes this argument. 

[4] This need to compare the size of links means that we need interval-level measurement scales, which we have in our trade data. But it also means that the requirement for dichotomizing variables to make them useful in many of the formal network analysis techniques will constrain us.

[5] The comparison of changes in the magnitude of international economic integration over time was the main focus of our earlier studies of trade and investment (Chase-Dunn, Kawano and Brewer 2000; Chase-Dunn, Jorgenson, Giem, Lio, Reifer and Rogers 2002).

[6] Currencies also need to be converted from current into constant values to take out the effects of inflation for purposes of comparisons across time.

[7] It is interesting to note that the density and level of inequality of the network both begin their respective upward and downward trends in 1895, the same year in which the upward swing of the long Kondratieff wave began. 

[8] We also intend to block the trade and conflict networks among core and upper tier semiperipheral countries using regular equivalence to see if the resulting blocks are similar. We will also compute degree, betweeness and flow centrality scores for the trade networks to see how the positions of countries change over time. This approach uses the full data at each point in time to compute scores for each node, and so it is superior to studying dyads.  The scores of countries on these network node attributes will be correlated over time to see how countries are stable or move in the networks. We will also block the data at each point in time into core and non-core groups and examine changes in the volume of flows within and between blocks