East
and West in
World-Systems
Evolution
Christopher Chase-Dunn
Institute for Research on
World-Systems
University of
California-Riverside
and
Thomas D. Hall
Sociology
Abstract:
This paper uses the comparative world-systems perspective to address issues
raised in Andre Gunder Frank’s world historical study of East Asia and Giovanni
Arrighi’s comparison of
To be presented at the
conference on Andre Gunder Frank’s Legacy of Critical
Social Science, April 11-13, 2008
Andre Gunder Frank’s legacy is deep and wide. He
was a founder of dependency theory and the world-systems perspective. He took
the idea of a whole historical system very seriously and his rereading of Adam
Smith has borne new fruit in Giovanni Arrighi’s (2007) recent comparison of
The comparative world-systems perspective uses
world-systems, defined as important and consequential interaction networks, to
describe and explain human socio-cultural evolution since the emergence of
language. It compares earlier and smaller regional world-systems to later and
larger continental and global world-systems in order to see the patterns of
structural change. The claim is that, at least since the emergence of
chiefdoms, much of human socio-cultural evolution cannot be explained without
using world-systems (rather than single societies) as the unit of analysis. This
is because semiperipheral societies have been an important source of innovation
and transformation in all world-systems that have core/periphery hierarchies (Chase-Dunn
& Hall 1997: Ch. 5).
Spatial
Boundaries of World-Systems
Before the global world-system emerged in the 19th
century CE nearly all regional systems were composed of spatially nested
interaction networks. There were smaller bulk goods networks (BGNs), in which
food and everyday raw materials were circulated. These were encompassed by
larger networks of sovereign polities that fought and allied with one another
(political-military networks – PMNs).[1]
These in turn were encompassed within even larger networks in which prestige
goods and information flowed (PGNs and INs).
Bulk goods and political-military networks were extremely important for
the reproduction or change in local socio-cultural structures in all systems.
Prestige goods networks were more important in some systems than in others, and
the nature of the functioning of prestige goods was different in some systems
than in others.[2]
Using nested interaction networks to define the spatial
boundaries of systems makes it possible to map the expansions and contractions
of interaction networks over time.[3] David Wilkinson (1987) produced a chronograph
of the expansion of what he originally called “Central Civilization” (a
political-military network) that began with 3rd millennium BCE
Mesopotamia and
Figure 1: East/West Networks Expand
and Merge
Figure 1 portrays the
expansion of state-based world-systems in both
This approach to bounding systems is much more
empirically explicit than that adopted by Andre Gunder Frank in his work on
5000 years of world system history (Frank and Gills 1993). Frank and some of
his followers (e.g. Chew 2001) seemed to think that there was already a global,
or at least a Eurasia-wide world-system 5000 years ago. This was an instance in
which “painting with broad strokes” missed a lot of important detail. The important volume by Arrighi, Hamashita
and Selden (2003) gets the spatial bounding of East-West connections mostly
right.
Semiperipheral
Development
Another important recurrent pattern that becomes
apparent once we use world-systems as the unit of analysis for analyzing socio-cultural
evolution is the phenomenon of “semiperipheral development.” This means that
semiperipheral groups are unusually prolific innovators of techniques that both
facilitate upward mobility and transform the basic logic of social reproduction.
This is not to say that all semiperipheral groups produce such transformational
actions, but rather that the semiperipheral location is more fertile ground for
the production of innovations than is either the core or the periphery. This is
because semiperipheral societies have access to both core and peripheral
cultural elements and techniques, and they have invested less in existing
organizational forms than core societies have. So they are freer to recombine
the organizational elements into new configurations and to invest in new
technologies, and they are usually more highly motivated to take risks than are
older core societies. Innovation in older core societies tends toward minor
improvements. Semiperipheral societies are more likely to put their resources
behind radically new concepts.
Thus
knowledge of core/periphery hierarchies and semiperipheral locations is
necessary for explaining how small-scale interchiefdom systems evolved into the
capitalist global political economy of today. The process of rise and fall of
powerful chiefdoms, called “cycling” by anthropologists (Anderson 1994; Hall
2001, 2006), was occasionally punctuated by the emergence of a polity from the
semiperipheral zone that conquered and united the old core region into a larger
chiefly polity or an early state. This phenomenon is termed the “semiperipheral
marcher chiefdom” (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997:83-84, Kirch 1984:199-202).
Much
better known is the analogous phenomenon of “semiperipheral marcher states” in
which a relatively new state from out on the edge of a core region conquered
adjacent states to form a new core-wide empire (Mann 1986; Collins 1981).
Almost every large conquest empire one can think of is an instance of this. A
less frequently perceived phenomenon that is a quite different type of
semiperipheral developed is the “semiperipheral capitalist city-state.” Dilmun,
early Ashur, the Phoenician cities, the Italian city-states, Melakka, and the
Hanseatic cities of the Baltic were instances. These small states in the
interstices of the tributary empires were agents of commodification long before
capitalism became predominant in the emergent core region of
The semiperipheral development idea is also an
important tool for understanding the real possibilities for global social
change today because semiperipheral countries are the main weak link in the
global capitalist system – the zone where the most powerful antisystemic
movements have emerged in the past and where vital and transformative
developments are most likely to occur in the future.
The
Idea of Evolution
It
remains necessary to clarify what we mean and what we do not mean by the word
“evolution.” Sanderson (1991; 2007) has explained that the scientific study of
evolution must be cleansed of certain assumptions that tend to be included by
most users of this word. We are not necessarily talking about “progress.”
Progress is an idea that requires specifying a set of desiderata, value
commitments, and assumptions about what is good and what is not. That is a fine
thing to do and we shall do it toward the end of this paper. Progress can be an
empirical question once one has defined what is meant. But the study of
evolutionary patterns of change need not assume either progress nor its
opposite, regress. It is simply a study of certain directional patterns of
change.
In general societies have gotten larger and more complex
and more hierarchical albeit with occasional reverses in these patterns. We
further note that new social forms most often arise out of a necessity fostered
by social interactions, resource shortages, climate change, diffusion of new
ideas, technologies, or microorganisms, and most typically a combination of one
or more of these. New social forms often appear via a satisficing mechanism:
the first form that is found to work is seized. As more versions appear (say
states) and come into competition a selection process favors those that can outproduce
and outfight the others, that is, a maximization process. However the
“selection pressure” is locally determined, both spatially and chronologically.
We also note that these changes, or evolution, are rarely linear, or even
smooth. Rather, they are marked by many reversals, collapses, fragmentations,
etc. (Hall 2006). Development of complexity often engenders other societies to
become more complex, though at times promotes break up or collapse to simpler forms.
Scientific explanations of evolutionary change do not employ purposes as causes
(teleology) and they do not assume inevitability.
Central and East
Asian Evolution since the Stone Age
East Asian complexity and
hierarchy emerged as sedentary agriculture developed in inland fertile valleys.
Horticultural settlements developed into chiefdoms and farmers traded and
fought with those groups that continued to rely primarily on hunting and
gathering. Eventually the hunter-gatherers were pushed onto the steppes, where
they shifted toward pastoralism. Thus began the long sedentary/nomadic dance
that was to have such huge consequences for the evolution of East Asian
world-systems. The pastoralists traded meat and live animals for grain. Some of
them settled on the edges of the region of sedentary polities to form new
semiperipheral chiefdoms, and later states. Often small states and nonstate
societies were linked by trade networks (Smith 2005).
In
It was not until the first century B.C. that the
The partial isolation of Chinese civilization from the
West was great enough to prevent the diffusion of phonetic writing, an
invention that spread widely in the West displacing earlier ideographic forms
of writing. By the time contacts with the West became more common, the Chinese
already had a substantial investment in a great literature written in their
ideographic script and this became the symbolic core of Eastern civilization
that could not be lightly thrown away in favor of a less cumbersome form of
representing language. Ideographic writing also had the advantage that it could
easily transcend dialect, and even language differences. It served as a lingua
franca, not unlike Latin in
Indeed, the silk road cities, and occasional statelets
were hotbeds of change, as would be expected in nodal areas. Recent works by
McNeill and McNeill (2003) and Christian (2004) have stressed the importance of
trade and communications networks in the processes of human socio-cultural
evolution. Both of these recent works employ a network node theory of
innovation and collective learning that is similar to the human ecology
approach developed earlier by Amos Hawley (1950). Innovations are said to be
unusually likely to occur at transportation and communications nodes where
information from many different sources can be easily combined and recombined.
This is one, but only one, of the reasons Andre Gunder
Frank (1992) argued for the Centrality of
Central Asia. Central Asian states seldom made the semiperipheral marcher
state transition – with the glaring exception of the Mongols (Hall 2005) – they
were conduits of change in many directions. Indeed, Central Asian nomads were
the vectors of many social changes, in all directions (for instance see
Barfield 1989; Kradin 2002; Kradin et al. 2003). For most of its four millennia history
Figure 2: Largest Empires in the East Asian Region
Figure 2 shows the
territorial sizes in square megameters of the largest states and empires in
East Asia from 1900 BCE to 206 BCE with the sequential upsweep carried out by
The history of core/periphery interaction in
Figure
3: Territorial sizes of largest states and empires in
Figure 3 shows the sizes
of the largest states and empires in
All these upward sweeps in the territorial sizes of empires involved
semiperipheral or peripheral marcher states. The Hsiung-nu were classic horse
pastoralist nomads who came out of
In his classic study, Inner
Asian Frontiers of China, Owen Lattimore graphically described the cycles
of Chinese dynasties thus(1940: 531):
Although
the social outlook of the Chinese is notable for the small honor it pays to
war, and although their social system does not give the soldier a high
position, every Chinese dynasty has risen out of a period war, and usually a
long period. Peasant rebellions have been as recurrent as barbarian invasions.
Frequently the two kinds of war have been simultaneous; both have usually been
accompanied by famine and devastation, and peace has never been restored
without savage repression. The brief chronicle of a Chinese dynasty is very
simple: a Chinese general or a barbarian conqueror establishes a peace which is
usually a peace of exhaustion. There follows a period of gradually increasing
prosperity as land is brought back under cultivation, and this passes into a
period of apparently unchanging stability. Gradually, however, weak administration
and corrupt government choke the flow of trade and taxes. Discontent and
poverty spread. The last emperor of the dynasty is often vicious and always
weak--as weak as the founder of the dynasty was ruthless. The great fight each
other for power, and the poor turn against all government. The dynasty ends,
and after an interval another begins, exactly as the last began, and runs the
same course.
Lattimore qualifies this characterization for different
periods. But it remains an
insightful description of a process that repeated itself over the centuries
until
Reorient and Largest Cities: The Timing of the
Rise of the West
Andre Gunder Frank’s (1998) provocative study of the
global economy from 1400 to 1800 CE contended that
Frank’s
model of development is basically a combination of state expansion and
financial accumulation, although in Reorient he focused almost
exclusively on financial centrality as the major important element. His study
of global flows of specie, especially silver, is an important contribution to
our understanding of what happened between 1400 and 1800 CE. Frank also uses
demographic weight, and especially population growth and growth of the size of
cities, as an indicator of relative importance and developmental success.
Figure 4: Regional Urban Population as a % of the World’s Largest Cities
In Figure 4 we see the
emergence of the world’s first cities in Mesopotamia and
The
relative size-importance of European cities (indicated by the solid line) shows
a long oscillation around a low level, indicating
All
the largest cities on Earth, including those in the
The
trajectory of
For
Frank’s
depiction of a sudden and radical decline of
Our
examination of the problem of the relative importance of regions relies
exclusively on the population sizes of cities, a less than ideal indicator of
power and relative centrality.[4]
Nevertheless, these results suggest some possible problems with Andre Gunder
Frank’s (1998) characterization of the relationship between Europe and
Counter
to Frank’s contention, however, the rise of European hegemony was not a sudden
conjunctural event that was due solely to a developmental crisis in
This process of regional core formation and its associated emphasis on capitalist commodity production further spread and institutionalized the logic of capitalist accumulation by defeating the efforts of territorial empires (Hapsburgs, Napoleonic France) to return the expanding European core to a more tributary mode of accumulation.
Acknowledging some of the
unique qualities of the emerging European hegemony does not require us to
ignore the important continuities that also existed as well as the
consequential ways in which European developments were linked with processes
going on in the rest of the Afroeurasian world-system. The more recent emergence of East Asian cities as
again the very largest cities on Earth occurred in a context that was
structurally and developmentally distinct from the multi-core system that still
existed in 1800 CE. Now there is only one core because all core states are
directly interacting with one another. While the multi-core system prior to the
eighteenth century was undoubtedly systemically integrated to an important
extent, it was not as interdependent as the global world-system has now become.
A
new East Asian hegemony is by no means a certainty, as both the
Modes of Accumulation
and the East/West Comparison
In 1989 Gunder Frank wrote the first version of his
contention that “the modes of production” distinction made by Marxists is just so
much ideological nonsense (Frank 1989).[5]
He had discovered that something very like capitalism existed in the ancient
and classical worlds, and he had become quite skeptical about the idea of the
transition from feudalism to capitalism in
This
conceptual move on Frank’s part was arguably an over-reaction to some very important
but not well-understood insights – that markets, money, merchant capitalism,
finance capitalism, capitalist manufacturing and wage labor had played a much
more important role in the ancient and classical worlds than many others had
recognized, and that much of the Marxist version of the transformation of modes
of production was very Eurocentric. Furthermore, as did many others by 1989, Frank
came to see the
Our own position is that there, indeed, have been major transformations
in the modes of accumulation. One reason both Frank, and to lesser extent
Arrighi, miss this is that they start their histories well after states have
been invented. We however (1997) start about 12 millennia ago, and recognize,
along with many anthropologists, that the invention of the state is itself a
major shift, marking the invention of the tributary modes of accumulation. That
this transition has occurred independently several times in human history
indicates that it is part of a regular process of socio-cultural evolution (Sanderson 1999; Chase-Dunn and Lerro forthcoming; Hall and
Chase-Dunn 2006).
In our 1997 book, Rise
and Demise, we characterized
Taxation, tribute-gathering and rents from landed
property were the mainstays of the state and the ruling class. Paper money was used in Sung China in the 10th
century CE. But the state and the ruling class of mandarins, or the
marcher-state usurpers who sometimes came to power, were mainly dependent on
the use of state coercion to extract surplus product from the direct producers.
This is rather different from a capitalist system in which profit-making and
the appropriation of surplus value through employment of wage labor has become
the mainstay of the state and the ruling class.
In Volume 1 of The
Modern World-System Immanuel Wallerstein (1974) noted a key difference
between
This explanation was rejected as so much Eurocentric
claptrap by Frank, because Max Weber and Karl Marx had said as much, and they
needed to be thrown into the dustbin of Eurocentrism with all the other dead
white guys. In Adam Smith Giovanni
Arrighi, reviews and recasts the recent work on Chinese economic history that
has been partly inspired by Gunder Frank’s analysis (e.g. Bin Wong 1997; Kenneth
Pomeranz 2000; Kaoru Sugihara 2003) These
authors show extensive markets, commodity production, buyer-driven commodity
chains, etc. in China and confirm that Chinese economic institutions in 1900
were not inferior to those of the West.
Arrighi (2007) ends up with the conclusion that the key question is “who
controls the state?” In
One may ask what happened to capitalist efforts to gain
state power in
Giovanni Arrighi’s Adam
Smith in Beijing is dedicated to Andre Gunder Frank and Frank’s influence
is obvious throughout. Arrighi does not accept Frank’s blanket rejection of the
distinction between the tributary mode of accumulation and the capitalism mode
of accumulation. In The Long Twentieth
Century Arrighi describes
Both Frank and Arrighi share the conviction that
Arrighi contends that the kind of market society that is
said to be emerging in
Arrighi further contends that
The notion that China concentrated only on domestic
problems after the Ming abandonment of the treasure fleets is contradicted by
Peter Perdue’s (2005) careful study of Qing expansion in Central Asia, and the
notion that China is an exemplar of contemporary egalitarianism in relations
with the periphery is contradicted by the situation in Tibet and by many
observers of Chinese projects in Africa. While we do not condone China-bashing,
and we agree with Arrighi that China is a somewhat more progressive force in
world society than many other powerful actors, (including the current U.S.
regime) the idea that adoption of the Chinese model of political economy,
so-called market society, can be the main basis of a more egalitarian, just,
and sustainable form of global governance is a bit of a stretch. On the other
hand there are important elements of the idea of market society that probably
are quite relevant for a formulation of what should be the goals of
contemporary progressives, and that are possibly achievable during the twenty-first
century. (more below).
World
Revolutions and
As far as we know the idea of world revolutions was first developed by Terry Hopkins, Immanuel Wallerstein and Giovanni Arrighi in their 1989 book Antisystemic Movements (Arrighi, Hopkins and Wallerstein 1989). The idea is that the structure of global governance in the modern world-system evolves because of competition among core states for hegemony and because subordinated groups of people resist oppression and domination. These latter forms of resistance coalesce when local and national social movements, uprisings, rebellions and revolutions cluster in time, and as these subordinate groups increasing become connected to one another across space. Arrighi, Hopkins and Wallerstein (1989) analyzed the world revolutions of 1848, 1917, 1968 and 1989. They contend that the demands put forth in a world revolution do not usually become institutionalized until a consolidating revolt has occurred, or until the next world revolution. So the revolutionaries appear to have lost in the failure of their most radical demands, but enlightened conservatives who are trying to manage hegemony end up incorporating the reforms that were earlier radical demands into the current world order.
Up until the nineteenth centuries movements of
resistance in the East and the West were mainly disconnected with one another.
In
Rerise of the
Global Left
We agree with Arrighi that the current rise of
The world revolution of “20xx” (twenty dos equis) is
going on now (Chase-Dunn 2008). There are many continuities with earlier
revolutions, and we substantially agree with Arrighi’s specification of how the
decline of
The family of antisystemic movements in the global
justice movement of movements has achieved some recent successes, and has
endured some failures. There has not been much in the way of domestic violence
or divorce, but some new relatives have appeared and some of these either want
to move into the house or refuse to do so. Nevertheless, a multicentric and
strongly linked network of movements has emerged in the context of the World
Social Forum process (Chase-Dunn et al
2007). The labor movement is no longer hegemonic on the Left, even in its own
eyes. Most of the labor activists in the global justice movement now see a big
tent in which labor plays an important role, but is only one of several other
important players (Santos 2006).
What Exactly
is Wrong with Capitalism?
The ideological hegemony of neoliberalism has been a
useful foil for encouraging social movements and NGOs to scale up their
activities -- to become more transnational and to form global networks of
opposition. If a problem is obviously
not resolvable at the local or national level, people will make larger
coalitions and create global networks, as many (but not all) have done (Reitan
2007).
But the neoliberal boogeyman has also created some
problems for the orientation of the movements.
Because neoliberals use “market magic” as a justification for attacking
and dismantling all institutions that operate to protect the interests of
workers or the poor, this encourages movement leaders and writers to go back to
railing about commodification and commercialism, as the Marxist left has done
in the past. Karl Polanyi’s works on the negative properties of disembedded markets
have had an understandable resurgence of popularity. Some of this is good
because it gives people a way to resist the arguments of the neoliberal
ideologues. And some of it is good because the notion fair trade is a valuable part
of local and North/South altruistic solidarity. But it would be unwise to carry
the anti-market sentiment as far as was done in the
This raises the issue of what is really wrong with
capitalism. Most Leftist agree that capitalism destroys the environment,
exacerbates social inequalities and leaves vast numbers of people in extreme
poverty and bad health. But what is it about the institutional features of
capitalism that cause these negative outcomes?
For his analyses of the evolution of hegemony Giovanni
Arrighi has adopted a Braudelian understanding of capitalism that contrasts the
local market economy (which is not capitalism) with haute finance, which is capitalism. We agree with the part about
the relative worthiness of small commodity production. But we think that a contemporary political
analysis needs to once again also consider the issue of the institutional
nature of property. Private property in
the major means of production (meaning large private firms) is an important
institutional form of modern capitalism. No one now advocates the expansion of
state-owned firms as the solution to the problems created by capitalism because
the
As we have said above, Giovanni Arrighi suggests in Adam Smith that a more benign form of
market economy is emerging in
The Chinese use the term “market socialism” to describe
there own model. At present this seems to mean a state managed by the Communist
Party and a market society in which private ownership of the major means of
production is allowed.
Whether or not
This said, we think that simply extended social democracy
to the global level as advocated by the LSE scholars and others, does not
address the more fundamental issues of economic democracy that must be
addressed in moving toward a more just and sustainable world society. Boswell
and Chase-Dunn (2000) outlined a modified version of John Roemer’s model of
market socialism in which capital itself is socialized (see also Loy
Forthcoming).
Left cosmopolitans are advocating globalization from
below, while indigenous peoples and some neo-anarchists and autonomists simply
want self-reliance and the right to do what they want to do without
interference. These are huge issues and they reverberate in East-West
relations. There has been very little participation by people from the People’s
Republic of
Multilateral
Global Governance
Though
Arrighi does not specifically address the issue of hegemonic evolution, it is a
topic that his analysis of the past of and of
We
extend Arrighi’s analysis of the evolution of hegemony in the following way.
The next hegemon will not be a single state and neither will it be the European
Union, which is about the same size economically as the
Bibliography
Anderson, E. N. and Christopher Chase-Dunn “The
Rise and Fall of Great Powers” in
Christopher Chase-Dunn and E.N. Anderson (eds.) 2005. The Historical
Evolution of World-Systems.
Anthony, David W. 1998.
“The Opening of the Eurasian Steppe at 2000 BCE.” Pp. 94-113 in The Bronze Age
and Early Iron Age Peoples of Eastern Central Asia, edited by Victor Mair, Vol.
1.
Appelbaum, Richard and
William I. Robinson (eds.) Critical
Globalization Studies.
Arrighi, Giovanni 1994 The Long Twentieth Century.
Arrighi, Giovanni, Takeshi Hamashita, and Mark
Selden 2003 The Resurgence of
500, 150 and 50 Year Perspectives.
Arrighi, Giovanni. 2006. “Spatial and other
‘fixes’ of historical capitalism” Pp. 201-212 in C., Chase-Dunn and Salvatore
Babones (eds.) Global Social Change: Historical and Comparative Perspectives.
_____. 2007 Adam Smith in
Arrighi, Giovanni, Terence K. Hopkins and Immanuel
Wallerstein. 1989. Antisystemic Movements.
Arrighi, Giovanni and
Beverly Silver 1999 Chaos and Governance
in the Modern World-
System: Comparing Hegemonic Transitions.
Barfield, Thomas
J. 1989. The Perilous Frontier: Nomadic
Empires and
_____. 1992. “Response to Frank’s Centrality of
Central Asia.” Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars 24:2(April-June):76-79.
_____. 2001a. “Steppe Empires,
_____. 2001b.
“The Shadow Empires:
Beckwith,
Bentley, Jerry
H. 1993.
Bergesen,
Albert and Ronald Schoenberg 1980 “Long waves of colonial expansion and
contraction 1415-1969” Pp. 231-278 in Albert Bergesen (ed.) Studies of the
Modern World-System.
Boli, John and George M. Thomas (eds.) 1999 Constructing world culture : international
nongovernmental
organizations since 1875
Boswell, Terry and Christopher
Chase-Dunn 2000 The Spiral of Capitalism
and
Socialism: Toward Global Democracy.
_____. 2000 "From state socialism to global
democracy: the transnational politics of the modern world-system." Pp.
289-306 in Thomas D. Hall (ed.) A World-Systems Reader: New Perspectives on
Gender, Urbanism, Cultures, Indigenous Peoples, and Ecology.
Bunker, Stephen and Paul
Ciccantell. 2004. Globalization and the Race for Resources.
MD:
Chase-Dunn,
Christopher. 1990 "World state formation: historical processes and
emergent necessity" Political Geography Quarterly, 9,2: 108-30
(April).
Chase-Dunn, Christopher
1998 Global Formation: Structures of the
World-Economy (2nd
ed.)
Chase-Dunn, Christopher. 1999. "Globalization:
A World-Systems Perspective" Journal of World-Systems Research
5:2:165-185.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher. 2005. “Global public
social science.” The American Sociologist
36,3-4:121-132 (Fall/Winter). Reprinted
Pp. 179-194 in
(ed.)
Public Sociology: The Contemporary Debate.
Transnaction
Press.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher 2007. “Sociocultural
evolution and the future of world society.”
World
Futures 63,5-6:408-424.
Chase-Dunn,
Christopher 2008 “The
World Revolution of 20xx” Jerry Harris
(ed.) GSA Papers 2007: Contested
Terrains of Globalization.
ChangeMaker.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher and E.N. Anderson (eds.)
2005. The
Historical Evolution of World-Systems.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher and Salvatore Babones. 2007.
Global Social Change.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher and
Terry Boswell 1999 "Postcommunism
and the Global
Commonwealth" Humboldt Journal of Social
Relations 24,1-2: 195-219.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher and Bruce Lerro
Forthcoming, Social Change.
Bacon.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher and
Thomas D. Hall 1997 Rise and Demise: Comparing World-Systems.
Boulder, CO.: Westview.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Thomas Hall, & Peter Turchin. 2007.
“World-Systems in the Biogeosphere: Urbanization, State Formation, and Climate
Change Since the Iron Age.” Pp.132-148 in The
World System and the Earth System: Global Socioenvironmental Change and
Sustainability Since the Neolithic, edited by Alf Hornborg and Carole L.
Crumley.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Hiroko Inoue, Alexis Alvarez, and Richard Niemeyer 2008
“Global State Formation In World Historical Perspective” in Yildiz Atasoy (ed).
World Hegemonic Transformations, The State and Crisis in Neoliberalism. London & New
York : Routledge.
Chase-Dunn, C. and
Andrew K. Jorgenson, “Regions and Interaction Networks: an
institutional materialist perspective,” 2003 International
Journal of Comparative
Sociology 44,1:433-450.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Andrew
Jorgenson and Thomas Reifer 2005 "The Trajectory of the
Chase-Dunn, Christopher,
Yukio Kawano and Benjamin Brewer 2000 “Trade
globalization
since 1795: waves of integration in the world-system.”
American Sociological Review, February.
Chase-Dunn,
Christopher, Susan Manning, and Thomas D. Hall. 2000. "Rise and Fall: East-West Synchronicity
and Indic Exceptionalism Reexamined."
Social Science History
24:4(Winter):727-754.
Chase-Dunn,
Christopher and Susan Manning, 2002 "City systems and world-systems:
four millennia of city growth and decline," Cross-Cultural
Research 36, 4: 379-398 (November).
Chase-Dunn,
Christopher, Christine Petit, Richard Niemeyer, Robert A. Hanneman and Ellen
Reese 2007 “The Contours of Solidarity and Division Among Global
movements” International Journal of Peace Studies 12,2:1-15)
Chase-Dunn, Christopher and
Bruce Podobnik 1999 “The next world war: world-system cycles and trends” in Volker Bornschier and Christopher
Chase-Dunn (eds.) The
Future
of Global Conflict.
Chase-Dunn,
Christopher and Ellen Reese 2007 “Global party formation in world
historical perspective” Pp. 53-91 in
Katarina Sehm-Patomaki and Marlo Ulvila (eds.) Global Political Parties
Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Alexis Alvarez, Hiroko Inoue, Richard Niemeyer, Anders
Carlson, Ben Fierro and Kirk Lawrence 2006 “Upward Sweeps of Empire and City
Growth Since the Bronze Age” IROWS Working Paper #22. https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows22/irows22.htm
Chew, Sing 2001
World Ecological Degradation. Walnut
Cree, CA:
Christian,
David. Christian, David. 1998. A History
of
_____. 2004. Maps of Time.
Clark, Gregory 2008 “
Curtin, Philip 1984 Crosscultural Trade in World History. Cambrdige:
Danaher, Kevin (ed.) 2001
Democratizing the Global Economy: The
and the IMF.
Diamond, Jared.
1997. Guns, Germs, and
Steel: The Fates of Human
Societies.
Ekholm, Kasja and
Jonathan Friedman 1982 “’Capital’ imperialism and exploitation in the
ancient
world-systems” Review 6:1 (summer):
87-110.
Elvin, Mark. 1973. The Pattern of the Chinese Past.
Stanford:
Elvin, Mark 2004 The retreat of the elephants : an environmental history of
University
Press.
Engels, Frederic 1935 Socialism: Utopian and Scientific.
Fagan, Brian 2004 The Long Summer.
Fisher, William F. and
Thomas Ponniah 2003 Another World Is Possible.
Fitzpatrick, John. 1992. "The Middle Kingdom,
the
Florini, Ann 2005 The
Coming Democracy: New Rules for Running A
Frank, Andre Gunder. 1989. “Transitions and modes:
in imaginary Eurocentric Feudalism, Capitalism and Socialism, and the the Real
World System History.”
Frank, Andre Gunder.
1992. "The Centrality of
Number 8.
Frank, Andre Gunder 1998 Reorient: Global Economy in the Asian Age.
Berkeley, CA.:
Frank, Andre
Gunder and Barry K. Gills (eds.) 1993 The World System: Five Hundred Years
or Five Thousand ?
Friedman, Jonathan and Christopher Chase-Dunn
(eds.) 2005. Hegemonic Declines: Present and Past. Boulder, CO.:
Paradigm Press.
Gill, Stephen 2000
“Toward a post-modern prince? : the battle of
new politics of globalization” Millennium 29,1: 131-140
Hall, Thomas D. 2001. 2001. "Chiefdoms, States, Cycling, and
World-Systems Evolution: A Review Essay." Journal of World-Systems
Research 7:1(Spring):91-100 [E-Journal http://jwsr.ucr.edu/index.php].
_____. 2005. “Mongols in World-System History.”
Social Evolution & History 4:2(September): 89-118.
_____. 2006. “[Re] Periphalization,
[Re]Incorporation, Frontiers, and Nonstate Societies: Continuities and
Discontinuities in Globalization Processes.” Pp. 96-113 in Globalization and
Global History edited by Barry K. Gills and William R. Thompson.
Hall, Thomas D. and Christopher Chase-Dunn. 2006.
“Global Social Change in the Long Run.” Pp.33-58 in Global Social Change: Comparative
and Historical Perspectives, edited by Christopher Chase-Dunn, Salvatore
Babones.
Harvey, David 2003 The New Imperialism.
Hawley, Amos. 1950. Human Ecology: A Theory of Community Structure.
Held, David and Anthony
McGrew 2002 Globalization/Antiglobalization.
Hobsbawm, Eric 1994 The Age of Extremes: A History of the World,
1914-1991. New
Honeychurch, William and Chunag Amartuvshin. 2006.
“States on Horseback: The Rise of Inner Asian Confederations and Empires.” Pp.
255-278 in Archaeology of Asia,
edited by Miriam T. Stark.
Hung, Ho-Fung 2001 “Maritime capitalism in
seventeenth-century
_____________2005 “Contentious peasants,
paternalist state and arrested capitalism in
Historical
Evolution of World-Systems.
Johnson,
Chalmers 2000 Blowback: The Costs and
Consequences of American Empire.
Henry Holt.
Kaldor,
Mary 2003 Global Civil Society: An Answer
to War.
Keck, Margaret E. and
Kathryn Sinkink 1998 Activists Beyond
Borders: Advocacy
Networks in International Politics.
Kirch, Patrick V. 1984 The Evolution of
Polynesian Chiefdoms.
Koenig-Archibugi, Mathias 2008 “Is global
democracy possible?” A paper presented at the annual meeting of the
International Studies Association,
Kradin,
Nicholai. 2002. “Nomadism, Evolution and World-Systems: Pastoral Societies in Theories of Historical
Development.” Journal of World-Systems Research 8:3(Fall):368-388 [ejournal
http://jwsr.ucr.edu/index.php].
Kradin, Nikolay
N., Dmitri M. Bondarenko, Thomas J. Barfield, eds. 2003. Nomadic Pathways in Social Evolution. The Civilization Dimension Series, Vol. 5.
Lattimore,
Owen. 1940. Inner
Asian Frontiers of
_____. 1962. Studies in Frontier History: Collected Papers, 1928-58.
_____. 1980.
"The Periphery as Locus of Innovations." Pp. 205-208 in Centre and Periphery: Spatial
Variation in Politics, edited by Jean Gottmann.
Lee, J. S. 1931. “The Periodic Recurrence of
Internecine Wars in
Lee, J. S. (1933) in Studies Presented to Ts’ai
Yuan P’ei on His Sixty-fifth Birthday Part I, ed. Fellows and Assistants of
the Institute of History and Philology (
Levine, Marsha, Colin Renfrew & Katie Boyle,
eds. 2003. Prehistoric Steppe Adaptation
and the Horse. McDonald Institute Monographs.
Linduff, Katheryn M. 1998. “The Emergence and
Demise of Bronze-Producing Cultures Outside the Central Plain of
_____. 2003. “A Walk on the Wild Side: Late Shang
Appropriation of Horses in
Linebaugh, Peter and
Marcus Rediker. 2000. The Many-Headed Hydra: Sailors, Slaves, Commoners
and the Hidden History of the
Revolutionary
Liu, Xinru and Lynda Norene Shaffer. 2007. Connections across
Loy, Patrick Forthcoming “
Mair, Victor H., ed. 1998. The Bronze Age &
Early Iron Age Peoples of Eastern
Mair, Victor H. 2003. “The Horse in Late
Prehistoric
Mair, Victor H. ed. 2006. Contact and Exchange in
the Ancient World.
Martin, William G. et
al Forthcoming. Making Waves: Worldwide Social Movements, 1750-2005.
Mander, Jerry and Edward
Goldsmith (eds.) The Case Against The
Global Economy: and
For a Turn Toward the Local.
Markoff, John 1996 Waves of Democracy: Social Movements and
Political Change.
CA.: Pine Forge Press.
_____. 2006 “Globalization and the future of
democracy” Pp. 336-362 in C. Chase-Dunn and S. Babones, Global Social Change.
McMichael, Philip 1996 Development and Social Change: A Global
Perspective.
McNeill, William H. 1982. The Pursuit of Power: Technology, Armed Force, and Society since A.D. 1000.
McNeill, J.R. and William
McNeill 2003 The Human Web.
Modelski, George 2003
Modelski, George and William R. Thompson. 1996. Leading Sectors and
World Powers: The Coevolution of Global Politics and Economics. Columbia,
SC: University of South Carolina Press.
Moghadam, Valentine 2005 Globalizing Women.
Press.
Monbiot, George 2003 Manifesto for a
Murphy, Craig 1994
International Organization and Industrial
Change: Global Governance since 1850.
Pomeranz, Kenneth 2000 The Great Divergence:
Europe,
Economy. Princeton:
Puett, Michael. 1998. “
Purdue, Peter C. 2005
Rediker, Marcus B.
2007. The Slave Ship.
Renfrew, Colin. 2001. “The Indo-European Problem
and the Exploitation of the Eurasian Steppes: Questions of Time Depth.” Pp.
3-18 in Complex Societies of Central
Eurasia from the 3rd to the 1st Millennium BC: Regional Specifics in Light of
Global Models, V1 edited by Karlene Jones-Bley and D. G. Zdanovich.
Washington, D.C. Institute for the Study of
Reitan, Ruth. 2007. Global
Activism.
Robinson, William I 1996 Promoting Polyarchy: Globalization, US Intervention and
Hegemony.
_____. 2004 A Theory
of Global Capitalism.
University Press.
Roemer, John 1994. A Future for Socialism.
Ross, Robert and Kent Trachte 1990 Global Capitalism: The New Leviathan.
Rueschemeyer, Dietrich,
Evelyn Huber Stephens and John D. Stephens 1992
Capitalist Development and Democracy.
Sanderson,
Stephen K. 1990 Social Evolutionism.
_____. 1999. Social Transformations: A General
Theory of Historical Development, expanded edition.
_____.
2007 Evolutionism and Its Critics.
Santiago-Valles, Kelvin.
2005. “World historical ties among “spontaneous” slave rebellions
in the
Sassen, Saskia. 2006. Territory • Authority• Rights: From Medieval to Global Assemblages. Princeton ,
NJ: Princeton University Press
Scholte, Jan Aart.
2004. “Civil society and democratically accountable global governance.” Government and Opposition 39(2):211-233.
Sen, Jai and Madhuresh Kumar with Patrick Bond and Peter Waterman. 2007. A Political
Programme for the World Social Forum?: Democracy, Substance and Debate in the Bamako
Appeal and the Global Justice Movements. Indian Institute for Critical Action : Centre in
Movement (CACIM), New Delhi , India & the University of KwaZulu-Natal
Centre for Civil Society (CCS), Durban , South Africa . http://www.cacim.net/book/home.html
Sherratt, Andrew. 2003. “The Horse and the Wheel:
the Dialectics of Change in the Cirum-Pontic Region and Adjacent Areas,
4500-1500 BC.” Pp. 233-252 in Prehistoric Steppe
Adaptation and the Horse,
edited by Marsha Levine, Colin Renfrew & Katie Boyle. McDonald Institute
Monographs. Silver, Beverly 2003 Forces of Labor.
Shannon, Richard Thomas
1996 An Introduction to the World-systems
Perspective.
Silver,
waves, and cycles of hegemony," Review 18,1:155-92.
Silver, Beverly and Eric
Slater 1999 “The social origins of world hegemonies,” In
Arrighi
and Silver.
Smith, Jackie, Marina Karides, et al. 2007. The
World Social Forum and the Challenges of Global Democracy.
Smith, Monica.
2005. “Networks, Territories, and the Cartography of Ancient States,” Annals of the Association of American
Geographers 95:4:832-849.
So, Alvin. 1986. The South China Silk District: Local Historical Transformation and
World-System Theory.
So, Alvin Y.
1990. Social Change and Development:
Modernization, Dependency, and World-system Theory.
So, Alvin and
Stephen W.K. Chiu 1995
Stark, Miriam T., ed.
2006. Archaeology of
Starr, Amory. 2000. Naming
the Enemy: Anti-Corporate Movements Confront Globalization.
Zed Press.
Stevis, Dimitris and
Terry Boswell. 2007. Globalization and Labor. REST
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2002 Globalization and its Discontents.
Tarrow, Sidney. 2005. The
New Transnational Activism.
Tausch, Arno 2007 “War
cycles” Social Evolution and History
6,2: 39-74 (September).
Teggart, Frederick
J. 1939.
Tilly, Charles 2007 Democracy.
Turchin, Peter, Jonathan M. Adams, and Thomas D.
2006. “East-West Orientation of Historical Empires and
Turchin, Peter and Thomas D. Hall. 2003. “Spatial
Synchrony among and within World-Systems:
Insights from Theoretical Ecology.” Journal
of World-Systems Research 9:1(Winter):37-64 [ejournal: http://jwsr.ucr.edu/index.php].
Turchin,
Peter and Sergey Nefadov n.d. Secular
Cycles.
http://www.eeb.uconn.edu/people/turchin/SEC.htm
Turner, Jonathan H. 1995 Macrodynamics.
Underhill, Anne P. and
Junko Habu. 2006. “Early Communities in
Urry, John 1999
“Globalization and citizenship” Journal of World-Systems Research, Vol.
V, 2: 311-324.
Wagar, W.
Press.
_____. 1996 “Toward a
praxis of world integration,” Journal of
World-Systems
Research 2:1. Http://csf.colorado.edu/wsystems/jwsr.html
Wallerstein, Immanuel
1974 The Modern World-System, Volume
1.
__________________1984.
“The three instances of hegemony in the history of the
capitalist world-economy.” Pp. 100-108 in
Gerhard Lenski (ed.) Current Issues and
Research in Macrosociology, International Studies in Sociology and Social
Anthropology,
Vol. 37.
_____. 2000 The
Essential Wallerstein.
_____. 2004 World-Systems Analysis.
_____. 2007 “The World Social Forum: from defense
to offense”
http://www.sociologistswithoutborders.org/documents/WallersteinCommentary.pdf
Walton, John and David Seddon 1994 Free Markets and Food Riots: The Politics of
Global Adjustment
Waterman, Peter. 2006.
“Toward a Global Labor Charter Movement?” http://wsfworkshop.openspaceforum.net/twiki/tiki-read_article.php?articleId=6
Wilkinson, David. 1987 "Central civilization" Comparative Civilizations Review 17:31-59 (Fall).
_____. 1991 “Core, peripheries and civilizations,”
Pp. 113-166 in C. Chase-Dunn and T.D. Hall (eds.) Core/Periphery Relations
in Precapitalist Worlds.
Winant, Howard 2001 The World Is A Ghetto.
Wilmer, Franke1993 The Indigenous Voice in World Politics.
Wong, R. Bin 1997
[1] The PMN is an interacting system
of sovereign polities. This is what international relations scholars study as
the international system of national states, except that all world-systems have
this even if the polities are bands, tribes or chiefdoms instead of states.
[2] In the classical prestige goods
system a local elite monopolizes the importation of goods that are deemed to be
necessary for important social institutions such as marriage. If you must have a holy pot to get married
and Uncle Joe controls access to these pots then Joe has a lot of control over
when and who you marry. In other systems prestige goods function as a medium of
exchange that symbolizes alliances or as a stored form of wealth that allows a
group to trade for food during a time of scarcity instead of resorting to
raiding. This latter was the way that prestige goods were important in
indigenous
[3] The advantages of this approach
to spatial bounding of systems is argued more recently by Chase-Dunn and
Jorgenson (2003).
[4] For more discussion of this and
more evidence about the rise of
[5] This eventually became Chapter 6
of Frank and Gills (1993). In an earlier battle with Marxists Frank had
convincingly argued that the characterization of a systemic mode should include
more than production, and so he shifted to the term “mode of accumulation”
which we also adopted.
[6] Arrighi’s model of the evolution
of Western hegemonies contains a version of the oscillation back and forth
between network and corporate forms of organization (Arrighi 2006).
[7] We can note that the strongest
challenges to capitalism in the twentieth century came from semiperipheral
[8] Immanuel Wallerstein had his own
consideration of the issue of state scale in his analysis of hegemonies.