Comparing World-Systems:
Power, Size and warfare
The most up-to-date version of the data is at
let/conf/asa/asa17
“citypolity2017b” and powsize2
Christopher Chase-Dunn,
Hiroko Inoue and Levin Welch
For presentation at the meeting
of the American Sociological Association, Montreal, August 12-15, 2017, PEWS
Roundtable.
Institute for Research on
World-Systems
University of
California-Riverside
Draft 8-11-17; 13372 words
This is IROWS Working Paper # 108 available at (update)
https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows108/irows108.htm
The data Appendix to this
paper is at https://irows.ucr.edu/cd/appendices/powsize/powsizeapp.htm
Abstract: This study examines
the temporal relationships between the growth and decline of cities and empires
and changes in the distribution of power among states and changes in the amount
of interstate warfare in five whole interstate systems (world-systems) since 2700
BCE. World historians have long recognized that the population sizes of settlements
and the territorial sizes of polities have both increased over time and have
gone through cyclical growth and decline phases. This study uses whole interpolity
systems as the unit of analysis to address these questions: what are the causal
relationships between changes in the sizes of largest cities and empires? Does
empire growth cause city growth? Does city growth cause empire growth? And what
are the other causes of these size changes? Our earlier studies have found that
urban and polity upsweeps (large increases
in scale) are correlated over time. But the number of these instances of
large-scale change (upsweeps) is few. Much
more numerous are the smaller upswings in which the sizes of the largest
city or polity increased but did not become significantly larger than earlier
increases. Sweeps are large changes and swings are smaller changes. In this study,
we examine these more numerous urban and polity swings in those five
political-military interaction networks (PMNs) in which we have enough size
estimates to quantitatively study changes in the sizes of the largest cities
and empires. We will also take out the sweeps to see if there are patterned
differences in causation between larger and smaller changes. The interstate
systems that we study are those centered in Mesopotamia, Egypt, East Asia,
South Asia and the expanding Central Political-Military Network. Our main unit
of analysis is the political/military interaction network – a whole system of
interacting polities that are making war and military alliances with one
another. This is what international relations scholars call an “international
system.” We also examine the relationships between urban and polity swings and
changes in the power configuration of these same systems. Interstate power
configurations vary from decentralized to centralized based on the relative
sizes and power of the interacting states in each system. We also test the
relationship between urban and polity swings and changes in the intensity of
warfare in these systems. And we consider other potential causes of upswings
and upsweeps such as population growth, population pressure and trade intensity.
We also consider the possibility that the causes of downswings are different
from the causes of upswings. Add
summary of surprising findings.
Our earlier studies
(Inoue et al 2012, 2015) identified big
changes in the sizes of the largest settlements and polities in interstate
systems and world regions, which we call sweeps. An upsweep is an increase in
size that is at least 1/3 larger than the size of the three earlier size peaks.
But these upsweeps are somewhat rare. We found a total of eighteen urban
upsweeps in the five PMNs (interstate systems) studied (Inoue 2015: Table 7)
while there were thirty-six upswings. And we found only five urban downsweeps[1],
while there were thirty-two downswings (Inoue 2015: Table 8). Regarding polity size changes, we found
twenty-two upsweeps and fifty-nine upswings (Inoue 2012: Table 1); and nineteen
downsweeps versus fifty-eight downswings (Inoue 2012: Table 2). Our earlier
work identifies and focusses on sweeps because it is these large changes that
constitute the instances that account for the long-term trends toward larger
settlements and larger polities. But we also would like to know the patterns
and causes of smaller scale changes, and so here we analyze swings and see if
we get similar results when upsweep and downsweep events are taken out the time
series. (I ran the same
stats on swings w upsweeps taken out;
now need to take out the downsweeps to see what happens w that. )
We
deploy the comparative evolutionary world-systems perspective (Chase-Dunn and
Hall 1997; Chase-Dunn and Lerro 2014) to study and compare relatively small
regional world-systems[2]
with larger continental and global systems in order to study sociocultural
evolution.[3]
The concepts of the world-system perspective as developed by Immanuel
Wallerstein and others have been broadened to be useful for the analysis of
pre-capitalist systems. Thus we must be
able to abstract from scale in order to examine changes in the structural
patterns of small, medium and large whole human interaction networks. But in
this article we focus on medium-term
change in the scale of settlements and polities.[4]
In
the long run human settlements have tended to get larger, but our research has focuses
on medium-term sequences of growth and decline in order to identify those
upward sweeps (upsweeps) in which the scale significantly increased. Accurate
identification of these events facilitates our understanding of sociocultural
evolution because these were the events that constituted an important part of the
long-term trend toward larger, more complex and more hierarchical human social
institutions.[5]
World-systems are interacting sets of polities[6]
and settlements. Many, but not all, world-systems have been organized as
core/periphery hierarchies in which some polities exploited and dominated the
populations of other polities. Semiperipherality is an intermediate position
within such a core/periphery hierarchy. When we study whole interstate systems
we see that they all oscillate in what we call a normal cycle of growth and decline (see Figure 1). The largest
settlement or polity in each region reaches a peak size and then declines and
then this, or another, settlement or polity returns to the peak size again.
These cycles are usually not observed by looking at single settlements or
polities in isolation, but rather by looking at the largest settlement or polity within each region of interaction.[7]
Fig. 1. Types of Medium-term
Scale Change in the Largest Settlements or Polities
In Figure 1 the normal cycle of growth and
decline is half way down the figure and is labeled “normal growth and decline.”
At the top of Figure 1 is a depiction of an upward sweep (upsweep) in which the
size of the largest settlement or polity increases significantly. When an upward movement is sustained and a
higher level of scale becomes the new normal we call this an “upward sweep” or
an “upsweep.” We define an upsweep
as a peak that is more than 1/3 higher
than the average of the three immediately earlier peaks.[8]
We distinguish between an “upswing,”
which is any upturn in a growth/decline sequence, and an upsweep, which goes to
a level that is more than 1/3 higher than the average of three prior peaks.
We
want to explain the emergence and expansion of complexity and hierarchy in
social change. We note that there is a rough association between the scale of
settlements and polities and the degree of complexity and hierarchy. They are not the same thing but they tend to
be associated over many different systems and periods of time. There can be big
settlements without much complexity or hierarchy. There can be small polities that
have high levels of complexity and hierarchy.
These are only rough proxies. We use them because there are available
across time and space and make it possible to compare cultures that are rather
different from one another.
Hierarchy
and complexity tend to go together because an increase in complexity works
better if some institutions of coordination emerge to regulate and integrate
the more specialized parts. But there are non-hierarchical or less hierarchical
ways to do this, like the emergence of larger identities that encourage people
to cooperate with one another and the emergence of markets that motivate people
to coordinate their activities with one another.
Units of Analysis
Our approach to the spatial bounding of the unit of analysis is
very different from those who try to comprehend a single global system that has
existed for thousands of years. Gerhard Lenski (2005);
Andre Gunder Frank and Barry Gills (1994) and George Modelski (2002; Modelski, Devezas and
Thompson 2008) and Sing Chew (2001;2007) all analyze the entire globe as a
single system over the past several thousand years. We contend that this
approach misses very important differences in the nature and timing of the development
of complexity and hierarchy in different world regions that stem from the fact
that they were unconnected or only very weakly connected, with one another.
Combining apples and oranges into a single global bowl of fruit is a major
mistake that makes it more difficult to both describe and explain social
change. The claim that there has always been a single global world-system
before the rise of an intercontinental network is profoundly misleading.
In this chapter we use
Political-Military Networks ( PMNs) as the unit of analysis.[9] These are composed of
polities that are making wars and military alliances with one another. David
Wilkinson has carefully studied the spatial boundaries of these interstate
systems and we follow his lead in delineating them (Wilkinson 2017; Chase-Dunn,
Inoue and Neal 2018). Following Wilkinson’s (1987) specifications, the
timings of the incorporation of smaller PMNs into the Central PMN are as
follows: Egyptian and Mesopotamian PMNs merged to form the Central PMN in 1500
BCE; Europe was engulfed by the Central PMN in 500 BCE[10];
South Asia was engulfed into the Central PMN in 1750 CE[11];
and East Asia was engulfed into the Central PMN in 1830 CE.[12]
Modeling the causes of polity and settlement scale
changes
Our earlier research has shown that about half of
the upsweeps of polity and settlement sizes were associated with the conquest actions
of non-core (peripheral or semiperipheral) marcher states (Inoue, et al 2016). This partly confirms the
hypothesis that core/periphery relations and uneven development are important
for explaining the emergence of complexity and hierarchy in world-systems, but
it also shows that a significant portion of the upsweeps were not associated
with the actions of non-core marcher states. We are developing a multilevel
model (Inoue and Chase-Dunn 2017) that combines interpolity dynamics with the
“secular cycle” model developed by Turchin and Nefadov (2009). Our iteration model of the causes of the rise
of complexity and hierarchy also hypothesizes that these are both more likely
to increase in periods in which there has been greater interpolity conflict
(warfare). Interpolity conflict is a selection
mechanism. Polities that cannot mount a successful defense are likely to get
selected out along with their institutions and their people. But high levels of conflict also reduces
peoples’ resistance to hierarchy-formation. They are more likely to assent to
more centralized leadership and governmental institutions that provide order
and peace after they have been exposed to a long period of high conflict. This
works for both within-polity and between-polity conflict. We want to empirically
test this hypothesis by using data on warfare intensity for the cases in which
it is available.
This
study of swings will help us determine the nature of the relationships across
different political/military networks (PMNs). between urban and polity scale changes. To what extent is the timing of urban and
polity swings correlated? Since both go up over the long run, we seek to
determine their medium run relationship by calculating partial correlations
that take out the long-term trend by controlling for year as an independent
variable. We also examine graphs that show the track of largest city and polity
sizes together for each PMN. In order to
correlate urban and polity sizes we needed to produce time series of the two that
have the same time points. We have done this by using the estimates we have to
calculate linear interpolations for congruent years for each variable. For
Mesopotamia and Egypt we use 100 year intervals, while for South Asia, East
Asia and the Central PMN we use 50 year time points. Using 50 year intervals
for Egypt and Mesopotamia requires the use of too many interpolated data points
because the original estimates are too spread out in time. So we prefer to use
the more cautious 100 year intervals for these PMNs.
Estimating the population sizes of cities
We use the
compilations of estimates of the population sizes of cities published by Tertius
Chandler (1987), George Modelski (2003), and Ian Morris (2010) as our main
sources. Chandler’s (1987) data compendium uses several proxies to estimate
city populations: the number of households, the number of soldiers, estimates
of spatial size of the built-up area and the estimated population density per
unit of space. Sometimes he considers information about the number of houses of
worship or the number of public baths (Chandler 1987:2-12). Chandler‘s definition of a city includes the
resident population of the surrounding suburban areas – what is now called
“urban agglomerations.”
George Modelski
(2003:4) regarded cities as "the central places of area-wide interactions;
they facilitate the operation of the system, and in turn depend upon its
support". He argued that cities
(urban agglomerations) are "a manifestation of the growth of institutions
capable of organizing vast regions into integrated systems" (Modelski
2003: 4).[13]
Chandler’s and Modelski’s estimates of city population sizes have been
criticized for being rough approximations based on several proxies that did not
include archaeological evidence (Smith 2016a)
Ian Morris (2010: 107)
reviews the debates among demographers and urbanists about the definitions of
urban spatial boundaries and the reliability of census data. In his work, premodern settlement size
estimates are based on archaeological evidence of their areal size and
historical records (Morris 2010: 108). For modern cities Morris uses the definition
and estimates from the Economist Pocket
World in Figures, which bounds cities as urban agglomerations comprising a contiguous
built-up area (Economist 2008: 23).
From the comparisons
of these three data sources, we have found that Morris’s estimates are most
usually more conservative as to the sizes of cities compared with those of Modelski. Morris compiled his largest city size data
using multiple data sources. He selected
what he considered to be the best of the estimates among them, yet he was aware
that the use of a single data source (e.g. only using Modelski’s estimates)
makes it easier to amend errors since it provides more consistent errors
compared with using multiple sources (Morris 2010: 108).
We compiled our
estimates in a similar manner as Morris and followed the comprehensive approach
developed by Daniel Pasciuti (2002). In
our data compendium of city population estimates archived at the IROWS,[14]
we include all the estimates from all the sources, but in this research, we
used what we have judged to be the best estimate from the three sources and
supplemented with other sources from archaeology and history.
We define settlements as a spatially contiguous built-up area. This is the best definition for
comparing the sizes of settlements across different polities and cultures
because it ignores the complicated issue of governance boundaries (e.g.
municipal districts, etc.). But it still has some problems. Most cultures have
nucleated settlements in which residential areas surround a monumental,
governmental or commercial center. In such cases it is fairly easy to spatially
bound a contiguous built up area based on the declining spatial density of
human constructions. But other cultures space residences out rather than
concentrating them near a central place (e.g. many of the settlements in the preshistoric American Southwest such as Chaco Canyon). In these cases it is necessary to choose a
standard radius from the center in order to make comparisons of population
sizes over time or across cultures.
Estimating the territorial sizes of polities
What we want to know is the size of the area over which a central power
exercises a degree of control that allows it to appropriate important resources
(taxes and tribute). The ability to extract resources falls off with
distance from the center in all polities, and controlling larger and larger
territories requires the invention of new transportation, communications and
organizational technologies (what Michael Mann (1986) has called “techniques of
power”). Military technologies and bureaucracies are important institutional
inventions that make possible the extraction of resources over great distances,
but so are new religious ideologies and new technologies of communication
(Innis 1950).
Of course, territorial
size is only a rough indicator of the power of a polity because areas are not
equally significant with regard to their ability to supply resources. A desert
empire may be large but weak. But this rough indicator is quantitatively measurable
in different world regions over long periods of time, so it is valuable for
comparative historical research.
Estimating the
territorial sizes of states and empires is usually based on the use of
published historical atlases. For the ancient and classical worlds, these are
based primarily on documentary evidence about who conquered which city, and
whether or not and for how long tribute was paid to the conquering polity.[15]
Sometimes it is difficult to tell whether or not tribute is asymmetrical or
symmetrical exchange. Only asymmetrical (unequal) exchange signifies a
tributary imperial relationship. Otherwise it is just trade and does not
signify an extractive relationship.
Most of the large
ancient and classical empires involved the conquest of territory that was
contiguous with the home territory. But once naval power was taken up by
tributary states an empire could conquer and dominate a client state that was
far from its home territory, such as Rome’s control of areas on the south shore
of the Mediterranean Sea. If these distant non-contiguous tribute-payers were
small in number and size, not including them in the estimates of the
territorial sizes of empires would not constitute a large error. But, as
capitalism moved from the semiperiphery to the core, capitalist nation-states
increasingly adopted the thallasso cratic
form of empire that had been pioneered by semiperipheral capitalist city-states[16]—control
over distant overseas colonies. The modern colonial empires (British, French,
etc.) require estimating the territorial sizes of colonies that are spread
across the seas. The increasing institutionalization of the territorial
boundaries of states makes this much easier than it was in the ancient and
classical worlds in which polity boundaries were often quite fuzzy.
Not all maps in political atlases show the
boundaries of territorial control. They may represent linguistic or religious
groups or other distinctions that have little or nothing to do with state
power. And maps may not have good time resolution. Our data on the territorial
sizes of polities are mostly taken from the published articles of Rein
Taagepera (1978a, 1978b, 1979, 1997), except that some estimates for South Asia
have been added based on Schwartzberg (1992).
Power
Configurations
David Wilkinson (1996, 1999a, 2001, 2004a, 2004b, 2006) has coded
the power configurations of interstate systems by reading the histories of
battles and diplomacy. His coding scheme is based on seven polarity categories:
0= Nonpolarity; 1= Multipolarity; 2= Tripolarity ;3= Bipolarity ; 4=
Unipolarity (Non-hegemonic); 5= Hegemony;
6= Empire. These vary in terms of how
unequal is the distribution of power among states in an interacting network of
warfare and diplomacy based on Wilkinson’s judgments of the relative power of
the states in each system. Wilkinson sees these categorical polarities as
somewhat unique configurations, but it is also possible to use his categories
as a rough continuum that varies from very decentralized nonpolarity to a very
centralized situation of either hegemony or empire. It should be noted that
Wilkinson’s conception of hegemony (1994, 1999b, 2008) requires that the
hegemon has the power to enforce its wishes upon the other states of the
system.[17]
We should note here that there is a logical overlap between Wilkinson’s power
configuration variable and our measure of the territorial size of the largest
state in an interstate system. The size of the largest state is an
important component of power configuration, but it does not include any
information about the sizes of the other states. We expect that power
configuration and largest territorial state will be positively correlated, but
our research will show how large the positive relationship is and will show
when and where these two variables may diverge.
It should also be noted that
Wilkinson coded power configuration every 10 or 25 years.[18] We used those of his
codings that corresponded with the 50-year or 100-year time points at which we
have estimates of largest city population sizes and the territorial sizes of largest
empires.
Intensity of Interpolity Conflict
Warfare in interpolity systems
and conflict within polities are both important causes of sociocultural
evolution. Success or failure in warfare operates as a group selection
mechanism in the competition among polities, and different levels of internal
conflict and cooperation are also important conditions that have consequences
for how well polities do in competition with one another. International
relations political scientists hypothesize that the level of interpolity
conflict (warfare) is related to the distribution of power among a set of
interacting polities (less warfare in more centralized power configurations) and
the iteration model developed by Chase-Dunn and Hall (1997: Chapter 6) suggests
that upsweeps in complexity and hierarchy are more likely to emerge after
periods in which within-polity and between-polity conflicts have been relatively
high. We can test these hypotheses about the consequences of different levels
of interpolity conflict in those of our cases in which warfare events have been
coded over long periods of time. The most systematic efforts so far to develop
datasets on premodern warfare using primary sources have been carried out by
the Long-Range Analysis of War (LORANOW) project led by Claudio
Cioffi-Revilla. We will also use the
warfare events data coded by Peter Brecke (2001, nd) since 1400 CE for the
Central and East Asian PMNs.[19] And we will use the coding of East Asian
battles assembled by David Kang and his associates (Kang et al 2016). Our level of
interpolity conflict coding uses the number and length of wars and indicators
of war extent (the number of autonomous polities involve in a war; Cioffi and
Lai 2001) or severity (fatalities) to estimate the relative level of conflict
for each time period. Our codings of interpolity conflict intensity are
intended to be as comparable as possible across different war event data sets. We
begin with the dataset on ancient China produced by the LORANOW project and
then try to make other data sets comparable. Ideally each decade would receive
an interpolity conflict score that is the sum of the number of wars during that
decade, the sum of the number of years (durations) that wars occurred within
the decade, and the sum of the extents (the number of autonomous polities
involved in each war. Once severity estimates are available we will also add
these to produce our estimates of the relative intensity of interpolity
conflict for each time period. Because our other variables have very low temporal
resolution during early time periods (100 year or 50 year intervals) we will
also calculate war intensity for these long intervals.
Claudio
Cioffi-Revilla and David Lai’s (2001) data for Chinese warfare from 2700 BCE to
722 BCE estimates the onset and termination years for each war and a variable
they call “extent” which is an estimate of the total number of autonomous
polities involved in each war. Their indicator of extent varies from 2 to 9 in
the ancient China data set.. For later
periods when we have severity measures we will scale the relative sizes of
wars. [20] So for each time period the warfare intensity score equals the sum of
the number of wars that occur, the sum of the durations of
those wars that happened within the time period and the sum of the extents of
those wars. Figure A1 in the
Appendix plots the components of our Chinese interpolity warfare intensity
estimates from 1900 bce to 700 bce with 50-year intervals. . In Cioffi-Revilla
and Lai’s China data set there are some years that have more than one war (e.g.
987 bce). In this case we add the two wars together to produce our period
estimate of warfare intensity. Figure A2
in the Appendix plots the relationships between the war intensity variable,
power concentration, largest city sizes and the territorial sizes of the
largest state or empire in China from 1900 bce to 700 bce.
Testing Causal Hypotheses with Time Series Data
We present descriptive
statistics and we test for causality in the relationships among the variables
we are studying using Granger time-series tests of antecedence. The Granger
test uses the assumption that a cause must precede its consequence to estimate
the likelihood of causation among time series variables. Most of our variables are measured at
simultaneous time points (years), and the gaps between time points are large
(50 or 100 years). But for some of our variables we have better temporal
resolution. Some of Wilkinson’s power configuration estimates are for decades,
and for the war intensity variables we are able to construct decadal estimates
because we know the years of onset and conclusion of war events. For these
decadal variables, we can use precedence or antecedence to test for causation
and we can look at different time lags.
So, for example, to test whether or not high interpolity conflict is a
cause of upsweeps we can see if the decade before an upsweep is unusually high
with regard to the level of conflict. Or we can look at the previous two
decades. If we think upsweeps in the territorial sizes of largest polities
should suppress interpolity conflict we can see if the decades following a
polity upsweep are unusually low with regard to the level of interpolity
conflict.
Bivariate Correlations: Cities, States and Power Configuration
Time period |
State/city |
Powcon/city |
Powcon/state |
Year/city |
Year/state |
N |
|||||
Mesopotamia |
2700 -1500 bce |
-.09 |
.25 |
.14 |
-.66* |
.48 |
13 |
||||
Egypt |
2600 -1500 bce |
.39 |
-.62* |
-.01 |
.48 |
.45 |
12 |
||||
South Asia |
400 bce – 1750 ce |
.50 |
.09 |
.30 |
-22 |
.07 |
44 |
||||
East Asia |
1900 bce - 1800 ce |
.58** |
-.18 |
.20 |
.85** |
.63** |
75 |
||||
Central |
1500 bce – 700 ce |
-.19 |
-.25 |
.28 |
.48 |
-.42 |
17 |
||||
1500 bce – 1900 ce |
.63** |
-- |
-- |
.67** |
.72** |
69 |
|||||
Table 1: Bivariate correlation coefficients [21]
Added 1000-1750 ce to south asia; take south asia out of central from 1000cd to 1750ce. Use Cioffi
polarity to extend east asia back to -1900 when taagepera starts
Produce another descriptive table that also
includes the warfare variable for the cases for which we have it.
Table
1 shows the bivariate Pearson’s or Spearman’s correlation coefficients (r)
between power configuration (powcon), largest city size, and largest polity
size for each of the PMNs we are studying. For Egypt and Mesopotamia, we use
100 year intervals, but for the others we use 50 year intervals. David
Wilkinson has not yet finished coding power configuration for the Central PMN,
so the correlations between powcon, cities and states are only for the period
from 1500 BCE to 700 BCE. Table 1 also shows the time periods and the number of
time points (N) used to calculate the Pearson’s rs. And we also show the
correlations between cities and states with year to see how important the
long-term trend may be and how it may influence the other correlations. There
is no usual long-term trend for power configuration so we do not show its
correlations with year.
Table
1 reveals somewhat different patterns across the five PMNs. The state/city
bivariate correlation is generally positive, but slightly negative for
Mesopotamia during this time period. There is a positive and significantly high
correlation in the state/city bivariate correlation for East Asia.
The power
configuration/city correlation is highly negative and significant for the
Egyptian PMN, and it is negative for the Central PMN during the period for which
we have powcon estimates. It is positive
for Mesopotamia (.25) but nearly null for East Asia and South Asia (check the latter after adding
1000-1858 ce)
The power
configuration correlation with the size of the largest state is slightly
negative for Egypt, but positive for the other PMNs. The powcon/state bivariate correlation is
positive and significant for East Asia.
The correlation
between year and city is positive for the Central, East Asian, and Egyptian
PMNs, and it is significant for East Asian PMN.
The correlation between year and city is highly negative and significant
for South Asia (check)
and Mesopotamian PMN. The correlation between year and state is highly positive
and significant for East Asia, positive for Mesopotamian and Egyptian PMN. It is negative and significant for South Asia
(check), and
negative for Central PMN. More light can be shed on these correlations by
examination of the charts that plot the changes for each PMN (see below) but
first let us see what difference it makes if we take out the upsweeps and just
look at the city and polity upswings.
Probably take
out the following section. The method of
taking sweeps out is too messy
Swing Bivariate Correlations: Cities, States and Power Configuration
PMN |
Time period |
State/city |
Powcon/city |
Powcon/state |
Year/city |
Year/state |
N |
||||
Mesopotamia |
2700-2400/2100 -1500 bce |
-.09 |
.07 |
-.31 |
-.75 |
.80 |
11 |
||||
Egypt |
2600-2200/1800
-1700 bce |
.23 |
1 |
.23 |
-.66 |
-.06 |
7 |
||||
South Asia |
400 bce/50 bce – 1000 ce |
-.26 |
-.30 |
.18 |
-.08 |
-.30 |
23 |
||||
East Asia |
1900 bce - 650 bce/ 550 to 450 bce/ 250bce-550
ce/750 ce-1800 ce |
.48 |
.05 |
.41** |
.80 |
.58 |
47 |
||||
Central |
1500 bce – 1300
bce/1150-650bce/ 450-400bce/ 50bce-50ce/150-1200ce/1350-1650 ce |
.51 |
-- |
-- |
.58 |
.65 |
48 |
||||
Table 1.5: Swings without upsweeps Bivariate correlation coefficients [22] (see powsize1) add 1000ce-1858 ce to indic; take south asia out of central from 1000cd to 1858cd
Discuss results of taking out upsweeps or drop this whole bit.
Akkadian Empire
Figure 2:
Mesopotamia, 2700- (start earlier)1500 BCE (rescale powcon so it is more
visible)
Cioffi-Revilla (2001) has
identified the polities that were in interaction with one another in the
Mesopotamian/West Asian international system from 6000 BCE to 1500 BCE,
including the chiefdoms as well as the states and the empires. Figure 2 shows the trajectories of our three
variables for Mesopotamia during the period in the late Bronze and early Iron
ages for which we have David Wilkinson’s powcon estimates. Cities grew and then
got smaller during this period. The correlation between year and city size in
Table 1 is negative and statistically significant. The polity size story is
rather different. Polities grew slowly until the dramatic rise and fall of the
huge, but short-lived, Akkadian Empire. But then their upward trajectory
resumed, unlike that of cities in this time period. The Power Configuration
polarity sequence, which Wilkinson started coding in 2700 BCE, shows
oscillations that sometimes, but not always, follow the trajectory of the
territorial size of the largest polity. The Akkadian empire corresponds with a
rise in the centrality of the power configuration coding, but later territorial
size rises do not seem to track it. This results in the small positive
bivariate correlation between powcon and the size of the largest state (.14) shown in Table 1.
Figure 3: Egyptian
PMN, 2600 start earlier-1500
BCE rescale powcon
The story of the Egyptian
PMN is different. Cities generally got bigger, though with some downswings. This
confirms the .48 correlation
between year and city size in Table 1. The trajectories of city and state sizes
shows a positive relationship (r= .39) but there are also some important divergences. City size
seems to lead and state size to follow in the period from 2200 to 1800 BCE. Power configuration drops to non-polarity
during what appears to be a recovery of the size of the largest Egyptian
polity. The dips in polarity seem to follow declines in the size of the largest
polity. Both the city and the polity correlations with year are positive,
indicating the usual pattern of a long term upward trend.
Figure 4: South Asia PMN, 400 BCE-1750 CE
The
South Asia PMN displays some peculiarities noted elsewhere (Chase-Dunn, Manning
and Hall 2000). The huge size of the Mauryan Empire was not repeated in later
polity size upswings. Both the Delhi and the Mughal Empires were smaller.
Indeed, the correlation
between polity and year in Table 1 is -.39 and [recalculate the correlatons] statistically significant,
and the story is the same for city sizes (-.55). Nevertheless, the relationship
between city and polity sizes in positive (.12) which is obviously not due to a long-term
upward trend. They both go down and the swings are somewhat contemporaneous. The
power configuration variable swings the gamut from non-polar to empire and is
correlated .13 with the
size of the largest polity. The Mauryan
Empire was a peak for both power configuration and polity size and just follows
the largest peak of city sizes in the South Asia PMN. (Check)
Mongol Empire
Figure 5: East Asian PMN, 1900 BCE
The East Asian PMN graph contains 57 time points to
display change in our three variables from 1000 BCE until 1800 CE. All of the
correlations in Table 1 are positive and statistically significant. The only one that is not very
positive and statistically
no-significant is that between power configuration and city size (1.0). The bivariate correlation
between city and polity size is .64 and statistically significant. The Mongol Empire, which was an
important player in both the East Asian and the Central PMNs, shows a peak for both
powcon and the size of the largest polity in Figure 5.[23]
The correlation between power configuration and the size of the largest polity
in Table 1 is .50 and statistically significant. Both the trend correlations are high
(city/year .82 with
statistical significance and state/year .69 with statistical significance) so detrending is
needed to see what happens with the state/city correlation.
Figure 6: Central PMN, 1500 BCE-1800 CE
Figure 6 shows the power configuration
variable from 1500 BCE to 700 BCE, the time period that David Wilkinson (2004b)
has coded. The scale in Figure 6 makes it difficult to see what is happening
with the size of the largest polity in this period, but the Pearson’s r
correlation between polity size and power configuration for the seventeen time
points in this period is .28. The correlation between power configuration and
city size for this same period is -.25 (see Table 1 above). A graph for just this time period (1500
BCE to 700 BCE is in the appendix as Figure A1. It shows that there is a lot of
variation in power configuration during this period, and that some of its
relationship with changes in the largest polity size is positive, but in other
instances it is not. The bivariate correlation between
city and state size for the sixty-nine time points between 1500 BCE and 1900 CE
is .63 and it is statistically
significant[24]
This supports our notion that cities and
states cause each other. Both of the trend correlations are large, positive, and statistically significant
for the Central PMN (city/year = .67; state/year = .72) so the city/state correlation
should be detrended to see whether or not the medium term variations are
correlated when the long-term trend is removed.
Partial correlations between cities and states controlling for year
The following tables report the partial correlation
coefficients between largest cities and states when year is held constant in
order to remove the long-term trends to see if medium term swings are
correlated. We also report the partial
correlations between city, state and power configuration for the periods in
which the latter estimates are available.
The first set of tables looks only at cities and states because we have
longer time periods for just these two. The second set of table looks at these
plus the power configuration variable but for generally shorter periods of
time.
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
Mesopotamia (-4500- to -1500) n=31[25] |
Mesopotamia (-2700 to -1500)n=13 |
||
city |
state |
state |
||
Mesopotamia (-4500 to -1500) |
city Sig.(2-tailed) |
- |
0.58 (.763) |
.16 (.62) |
state Sig.(2-tailed) |
0.58 (.763) |
- |
|
Table 2:
Mesopotamian PMN (-4500 to -1500) (100 year intervals)
Table 2 shows that controlling for year changes the
Mesopotamian correlation between city and state from the -.09 shown in Table 1 to .16
for the period from 2700 BCE to 1500 BCE. Controlling for year removes the
negative bivariate correlation between year and city size (-66 in Table 1) which allows
the positive relationship between city size and polity size to become visible.
The longer term partial correlation between city and state sizes (4500 BCE to
1500 BCE is also positive (.58).
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
Egyptian PMN (-3200 to -1500) n=18 |
Egyptian PMN -2600 to -1500 n=12 |
||
city |
state |
state |
||
Egyptian PMN (-3200 to -1500) |
city Sig.(2-tailed) |
- |
.25 (.323) |
.34 (.312) |
state Sig.(2-tailed) |
.25 (.323) |
- |
|
Table 3: Egyptian
PMN (-3200 to -1500) (100 year intervals)
Table 3 shows that the Egyptian correlation between
city and state for the period between 2600 BCE and 1500 BCE changes from .39 (Table 1) to .34 when
year is controlled. The positive bivariate correlations of both city and polity
sizes with year were accounting for part of the positive correlation between
city and polity sizes. The longer term partial correlation (3200 BCE to 1500
BCE) is also positive (.25).
Add
1000-1858ce
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
South Asian PMN (-600 and 1000)n=33 |
||
city |
state |
||
South Asian PMN (-600 and 1000) |
city |
- |
.38* (.032) |
state |
.38* (.032) |
- |
Table 4: South
Asian PMN (-600 and 1000) (50 year intervals, N=29)
Table 4 shows that the city and state correlation
for the South Asian PMN changes from .12 to .38 when year is controlled and this correlation is
statistically significant at the .05 level. Again the higher correlation arises
when year is controlled because the bivariate correlations with year are both
negative (see Table 1). (check)
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
East Asian PMN (-1900 to 1800)n=75 |
||
city |
state |
||
East Asian PMN (-1900 to 1800) |
city |
- |
.03 (.835) |
state |
.03 (.835) |
- |
Table 5: East Asian PMN (-1900 to 1800) (50 year interval; N=57)
Table 5 shows that the East Asian correlation is
reduced from .64 to .03 when year
is controlled. This indicates that the
very high long-term correlation of city size with year (.82 in
Table 1) was the main reason behind the positive bivariate correlation between
city and state in East Asia over the whole time period between 1900 BCE and
1800 CE.
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
East Asian PMN (-1900 to 1)n=39 |
||
city |
state |
||
East Asian PMN (-1900 to 1) |
city |
- |
.49** (.002) |
state Sig.(2-tailed) |
.49** (.002) |
- |
Table 6: East Asian PMN (-1900 to 1)
But when we separate the East Asian data into two
subperiods we find something interesting. The partial correlation between city
and state is positive and statistically significant for the period before the Common
Era (BCE) (.49** in Table 6) but slightly negative for the period of the Common
Era (CE) (-.06 in Table 7).
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
East Asian PMN (1 to 1800) n=37 |
||
city |
state |
||
East Asian PMN (1 to 1800) |
city Sig.(2-tailed) |
- |
-.06 (.720) |
state Sig.(2-tailed) |
-.06 (.720) |
- |
Table 7: East Asian PMN (1 to 1800)
We do not know why the relationship between city
and year would be different in the two time periods.
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
Central PMN (-1500 and 1900)n=69 |
||
city |
state |
||
Central PMN (-1500 and 1900) |
city |
- |
.51*** (.000) |
state Sig.(2-tailed) |
.51*** (.000) |
- |
Table 8: Central PMN (-1500 and 1900) take south asia out of central from 1000cd to 1858cd
Table 8 shows that that state/city correlation for
the Central PMN declines from .63 (Table 1) to .51 when year is controlled, but
that the partial correlation is still rather statistically significant for the
whole period from 1500 BCE to 1900 CE. This indicates that the long term trend
accounted for some of the positive bivariate correlation, but that there is an
important medium-term positive relationship between cities and states for the
Central PMN.
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
Central PMN (-1500 and 1) n=31 |
||
city |
state |
||
Central PMN (-1500 and 1) |
city |
- |
-.21 (.264) |
state |
-.21 (.264) |
- |
Table 9: Central
PMN (-1500 and 1)
Table 9 looks at the subperiod before the advent of
the Common Era (BCE) for the Central PMN and shows a negative relationship
during this period, just the opposite of what we found for the East Asian PMN.
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
Central PMN (1 and 1900) n=39 |
||
city |
state |
||
Central PMN (1 and 1900) |
city |
- |
.54*** (.000) |
state Sig.(2-tailed) |
.54*** (.000) |
- |
Table 10: Central PMN (1 and 1900) take south asia out of central from 1000cd to 1858cd
The Common Era for the Central PMN shows as large
and statistically significant positive partial correlation between city and
state sizes. Again this is quite different from what we found for the Common
Era period of the East Asian PMN.
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
Mesopotamia (-2700 to -1500) n=13 |
|||
powcon |
state |
city |
||
Mesopotamia (-2700
to -1500) |
powcon |
- |
.16 (.618) |
.45 (.144) |
state |
.16 (.618) |
- |
.16 (.624) |
|
city Sig.(2-tailed) |
.45 (.144) |
.16 (.624) |
- |
Table 11: Mesopotamian PMN (2700 to 1500 BCE) (N=13)
Table 11 shows that the partial correlation between
Mesopotamian power configuration and city size for the period between 2700 BCE
and 1500 BCE is .45. This is more positive than the bivariate correlation (.25), so controlling for year
increases this correlation. The partial
correlation between power configuration and the size of the largest polity is
.16, which is nearly the same as the bivariate correlation shown in Table 1 (.14). The logical overlap between these two
variables is not large enough to produce a very high positive correlation over
time in Mesopotamia.
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
Egyptian PMN (-2600 to -1500) n=12 |
|||
powcon |
state |
city |
||
Egyptian PMN (-2600 to
-1500) |
powcon |
- |
.40 (.224) |
-.46 (.158) |
state |
.40 (.224) |
- |
.34 (.312) |
|
city Sig.(2-tailed) |
-.46 (.158) |
.34 (.312) |
- |
Table 12: Egyptian PMN 2600 BCE to 1500 BCE
Table 12 shows that the Egyptian partial
correlation between city and power configuration is negative -.46, but it is
somewhat less negative than the bivariate correlation shown in Table 1 (-.62). This is because the bivariate correlation
between year and city is positive (.48) so controlling year lowers the negative partial
correlation. Also recall that the
partial correlation between powcon and city was positive .45 for the
Mesopotamian PMN. The partial correlation between state and power configuration
is.40 whereas the bivariate correlation in Table 1 was -.01.
Again this is because the bivariate correlation between state size and
year is .45 so controlling the long-term trend allows the positive short term
relationship to be visible. The partial correlation between powcon and state
size for Mesopotamia was .16.
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
South Asia PMN (-400 to 1000) n=29 |
|||
powcon |
state |
city |
||
South Asia PMN
(-400
to 1000) |
powcon |
- |
.19 (.333) |
.00 (.998) |
state |
.19 (.333) |
- |
.10 (.620) |
|
city Sig.(2-tailed) |
.00 (.998) |
.10 (.620) |
- |
Table 13: South Asia PMN add
1000-1858ce
Table 13 shows that the South Asian partial
correlation between city and state is .10, whereas the bivariate correlation in
Table 1 is .12 (see
also Figure 4). Recall that both city
and state are negatively correlated with year during this period in South Asia.
The partial correlation between city and power configuration is effectively zero,
whereas the bivariate correlation reported in Table 1 was .07 . The partial correlation
between state and power configuration is .19 whereas the bivariate correlation
in Table 1 was .13
Controlling for the long-term downward trends of city and state sizes increases the partial
correlations. (check)
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
East Asian PMN (-1000 to 1800) n=57 |
|||
powcon |
state |
city |
||
East Asian PMN (-1000 to 1800) |
powcon |
- |
.47** (.000) |
-.01 (.918) |
state |
.47** (.000) |
- |
.04 (.786) |
|
city Sig.(2-tailed) |
-.01 (.918) |
.04 (.786) |
- |
Table 14: East Asian PMN
Table 14 is for a somewhat shorter and more recent
period than Table 5 but the partial correlations between city and state are similar
(.02 and .04). The partial correlation
between power configuration and city is -.01 and that between power configuration
and state is .47 and is statistically significant (see also Figure 5). This must be due to the logical overlap
between the power configuration and the size of the largest state.
PMN / level Partial Correlation |
Central PMN
(-1500 to -700) n=17 |
|||
powcon |
state |
city |
||
Central PMN
(-1500 to -700) |
powcon |
- |
.34 (.199) |
-.51* (.04g5) |
state |
.34 (.199) |
- |
.01 (.959) |
|
city Sig.(2-tailed) |
-.51* (.045) |
.01 (.959) |
- |
Table 15: Central PMN
Table 15 is for a much shorter and earlier time
period than is used for Table 8. For
this early time period the state/city partial correlation is -.01 whereas for
the whole time period for which we have estimates shown in Table 8 the
correlation .51 and is statistically significant. This means that there are either important
period differences, or that the estimates for the earlier time periods are
unreliable or some combination of the two. The partial correlation between power configuration
and city in Table 15 is -.51, whereas the partial correlation between power configuration
and state is .34.
The
partial time series correlation results generally confirm the hypothesis that
changes in the sizes of cities and states are contiguous in time (see Table
16). Both the Egyptian and Mesopotamian PMNs are during the Bronze and Early
Iron ages, when estimates of the sizes of both cities and polities are less
reliable.[26]
We have already remarked that we had to rely on more interpolations for both of
these cases. We reduced the number of interpolations by using 100 year
intervals rather than 50 year intervals which should have reduced the errors. The
state/city partial correlations are positive for all of our cases, but barely
so for the East Asian PMN. This partly confirms our hypothesis that these two aspects
of size cause each other but it does not tell us which of these causes is
larger. For that we will turn to tests of Granger causality. We also do not
know why the interaction between city and state sizes is so weak in East Asia.
One possibility is the somewhat greater role of non-core marcher states in the
process of empire formation in East Asia. It is well-known that horse nomads
and forest peoples despised cities and could only reinvent themselves to become
an urban ruling class with great effort.
PMN |
Time period |
State/city (whole period) |
Powcon/city (shorter period) |
Powcon/state (shorter period) |
Mesopotamia |
4500-1500 bce |
0.58 |
.45 |
.16 |
Egypt |
2600-1500 bce |
.41 |
-.46 |
.40 |
South Asia |
600 bce- 1000 ce |
.38* |
.00 |
.19 |
East Asia |
1900 bce- 1800 ce |
.02 |
-.01 |
.47** |
Central |
1500 bce- 1900 ce |
.51*** |
-.51* |
.34 |
Table 16: Summary of Partial Correlations (add 1000=-1858ce to south asia)
take south asia out of central from 1000cd to 1858cd
Table 16 also shows big differences across the PMNs
in the partial correlations between city sizes and power configuration. There is a positive relationship in
Mesopotamia, but zero or negative relationships in the other PMNs. We would
generally suppose a positive relationship because of the expected positive connection
of both of these variables with the sizes of the largest polities. This idea
finds support in the case of Mesopotamia, but South Asia and East Asia have
nearly null partial correlations and Egypt and the Central PMN have rather
substantial negative partial correlations.
These results are confusing. The negative partial correlation between
city size and power configuration for the Central system may be due to the
temporally truncated time period for which estimates of power configuration are
available (see Figure 6 above).
The
findings regarding the partial correlations between power configuration and the
sizes of largest states are more consistent. All of the PMNs show positive
partial correlations. This is reassuring because of the noted logical
connection between these two variables.
Perhaps it is the rather small positive partial correlations in South
Asia (check)and
Mesopotamia that are the most noteworthy. In these cases, a substantial amount
of the variation in power configuration is not captured by the size of the
largest polity.
We also found curious subperiod
differences in the city/state relationships for both the East Asian and the
Central PMNs (Tables 6,7,9 and 10 above).
For the period from 1900 BCE to the beginning of the Common Era (CE) the
East Asian PMN had a significant positive relationship between the size of the
largest city and that of the largest polity (.49** in Table 6). Whereas for the
period from the beginning of the Common Era until 1800 CE the same correlation
is null (-.06 in Table 7). We noted above that non-core marcher states, more
important in East Asia than in the Central PMN, were somewhat anti-urban. But
this may not explain the subperiod findings for East Asia because non-core marchers
were already playing an important part in the BCE period (the Xiongnu). And the Central PMN also displays a curious
subperiod difference. Table 9 shows that
the city/state relationship for the Central PMN from 1500 BCE to the beginning
of the Common Era is .21 whereas for the period from the beginning of the
Common Era until 1900 CE it is .54*** (Table 10). So these two PMNs display rather different
subperiod results. Why?
Granger
Causality Tests
Granger causality tests identify lagged correlations
between two time-series variables. They examine temporal precedence of one
variable relative to another, and if it is proven, it indicates a possible
causality. In the test, panel vector
autoregression analysis assesses Granger causality among multiple time-series
variables. The test allows us to
determine whether the sum
of lagged values of variable A explains more of the variance in variable B than
lagged values of variable B itself. When
the test shows the evidence that lagged variable A values significantly predict
changes in variable B, there is Granger causality in the relationship between
variable A and B. The current study uses
either chi-squared tests or F-statistics depending on the sample size to test whether
or not we can reject the null hypothesis. [27]
We test the Granger causality of the three
variables—polity size upswings/upsweeps, city size upswings/upsweeps, and the
level of polarity—of each PMNs.
H1:
lagged values of independent variable X provide more information on the respective
dependent variable than lagged variable of dependent variable Y alone.
H0:
lagged values of dependent variable Y explain more information than the lagged
values of independent variable X explain about the variable of dependent
variable Y.
Granger causality tests assume that the data are
covariance stationary. The raw data of
the three variables in our study are not stationary. [28] Therefore, we logged and first differenced
the raw data to make the values stationary.
After these transformations of the raw data Granger causality inferences
should be valid (Freeman 1983; Goldstein 1988).
We tested the Granger
causality of the three variables: polity size, city size and polarity
level.
Polity
size is the largest territorial size of a polity within
a PMN at 100-year intervals or 50-year intervals. When the 50-year interval data are not
available, we interpolated the 100-year interval data points to obtain the
50-year data estimates. For Mesopotamia
and Egypt, we used the 100-year intervals since even the 100-year interval data
points are not all available. We
interpolated the missing data points to have the 100-year interval data points
for these two PMNs.
City
size is the largest population size of a city within in
a PMN at 100-year intervals or 50-year intervals. The interpolation was conducted in the same
manner with the polity size data. City
data also has the 100-year interval data points for Egypt and Mesopotamia for
the same reason with the polity data.
Polarity is measured using Wilkinson’s
scale. David Wilkinson's coding scheme
for polarity is: 0. Nonpolarity, 1. Multipolarity, 2. Tripolarity, 3.
Bipolarity, 4. Unipolarity (Non-hegemonic), 5. Hegemony, 6. Empire. We test the
hypotheses that these three variables may be causes of one another.
“Polity up” in
the following tables means the upsweeps or upswing of polity territorial
size. “City up” means the upsweeps or
upswing of city population size. “Polity up” in the following tables indicates
the unification toward the rule by a single Empire over an extended territory.
Mesopotamia
(Lag time 2, N=10)
The year period is 2700BCE to 1500BCE. The data
points: 100-year interval.
Equation (Dependent Variable) |
|
Excluded (Independent Variable) |
F |
p-value |
|
Polarity |
ß |
Polity up |
18.532 |
0.0205 |
|
Polarity |
ß |
City up |
34.251
|
0.0086 |
|
Polity up |
ß |
Polarity |
.14663 |
0.8694
|
|
Polity |
ß |
City ups |
.19633 |
0.8315 |
|
City upsweep |
ß |
Polarity |
6.1177 |
0.0874 |
|
City upsweep |
ß |
Polity upsweep |
.37433 |
0.7459 |
|
Table 17: Panel Vector Autoregression Tests for Granger Causality, Mesopotamia
The raw data was
transformed using log and first difference to ensure stationarity. F-test is used due to small sample size. The results show that the city size upsweep
(upswing) Granger cause the level of polarity, or level toward the unification
by a single polity (empire). The results
also reveal that the polity size upsweep (upswing) Granger cause the polarity
(the level toward the unification by a single polity (empire)). There is no significant Granger causality
between city size and polity size increase.
Egypt
(Lag time 2, N=9)
The year period is 2600BCE to 1500BCE. The data
points: 100-year interval
Equation (Dependent Variable) |
|
Excluded (Independent Variable) |
F |
p-value |
|
Polarity |
ß |
Polity up |
5.3034 |
0.1586 |
|
Polarity |
ß |
City up |
.18385 |
0.8447 |
|
Polity up |
ß |
Polarity |
1.2081 |
0.4529 |
|
Polity up |
ß |
City up |
.18385 |
0.8447 |
|
City up |
ß |
Polarity |
88.514 |
0.0112 |
|
City up |
ß |
Polity up |
44.008 |
0.0222 |
|
Table 18: Panel Vector Autoregression Tests for Granger Causality, Egypt
The raw data was
transformed using log and first difference to ensure stationarity. F-test is used due to small sample size. The results show that the polarity, or level
toward the unification by a single polity (empire) Granger cause city upsweep
(upswing). The results also reveal that
the polity size upsweep (upswing) Granger causes city size upsweep (upswing) in
Egypt.
East
Asia (lag time 2, N=54)
The data range is 1000BCE to 1800AD. The data points: 50-year interval
Equation (Dependent
Variable) |
|
Excluded
(Independent
Variable) |
χ2 |
p-value |
|
Polarity |
ß |
Polity up |
.43105 |
0.806 |
|
Polarity |
ß |
City up |
.12579 |
0.939 |
|
Polity up |
ß |
Polarity |
.04458 |
0.978 |
|
Polity up |
ß |
City up |
7.0693 |
0.029 |
|
City up |
ß |
Polarity |
1.7393 |
0.419 |
|
City up |
ß |
Polity up |
.03599 |
0.982 |
|
Table 19: Panel Vector Autoregression Tests for Granger Causality, East Asia
The raw data was transformed using log and first
difference to ensure stationarity. The
results also reveal that the city size upsweep (upswing) Granger cause polity
size upsweep (upswing).
South
Asia (Lag time 2, N=26)
The data range is:400BCE to 1000AD. The data
points: 50-year interval
Equation (Dependent
Variable) |
|
Excluded
(Independent
Variable) |
χ2 |
p-value |
|
Polarity |
ß |
Polity size |
.24277 |
0.886
|
|
Polarity |
ß |
City size |
.00593 |
0.992 |
|
Polity size |
ß |
Polarity |
8.8052 |
0.012 |
|
Polity size |
ß |
City size |
.22504 |
0.894 |
|
City up |
ß |
Polarity |
3.7068 |
0.157
|
|
City up |
ß |
Polity up |
6.1279
|
0.047 |
|
Table 20: Panel Vector Autoregression Tests for Granger Causality, South Asia (add 1000-1858ce)
The raw data was
transformed using log and first difference to ensure stationarity. F-test is used due to small sample
size. The results show that the level of
polarity (the level of unification toward a single polity/empire) Granger cause
polity up sweep (swing). The results
also reveal that the polity size upsweep (upswing) Granger cause city size
upsweep (upswing).
Central
PMN (Lag time 2, N=14)
The year period is 1500BCE to 700BCE. The data
points: 50-year interval
Equation (Dependent
Variable) |
|
Excluded
(Independent
Variable) |
F |
p-value |
|
Polarity |
ß |
Polity up |
1.6446 |
0.2597 |
|
Polarity |
ß |
City up |
.52839 |
0.6113 |
|
Polity up |
ß |
Polarity |
.98727 |
0.4191 |
|
Polity up |
ß |
City up |
.8995
|
0.4489 |
|
City up |
ß |
Polarity |
5.3985 |
0.0382 |
|
City up |
ß |
Polity up |
14.057 |
0.0035 |
|
Table 21: Panel Vector Autoregression Tests for Granger
Causality, Central PMN take south asia out of central
from 1000cd to 1858cd
The raw data was
transformed using log and first difference to ensure stationarity. F-statistics is used for Central PMN because
of the small sample size (14). The
results show that the level of polarity (the level of unification by a single
polity/empire) Granger cause city up sweep (swing). The results also reveal that the polity size
upsweep (upswing) Granger cause city size upsweep (upswing). Further, the polity size upsweep (upswing)
Granger cause the level of polarity.
Discussion and Conclusions
An
earlier study (Chase-Dunn, Alvarez and Pasciuti 2005) found positive
cross-temporal correlations in several world regions in the relationship
between the territorial sizes of the largest and the second largest states
(Taagepera 1978a: 116). This was
surprising because of the hypotheses that territorial sizes of states is
somewhat of a zero-sum game. If one
state has a lot of territory there is less available for other states. This
finding was interpreted to mean that world regions experience periods of growth
in which states are generally getting larger and periods of decline in which
states are getting smaller, thus producing the positive cross-temporal
correlations between largest and second largest states. If this is true it has
implications for our study of the relationships between cities and states. The
positive correlations, when they exist, may be due to these regional
growth/decline phases. Add discussion of granger
results From Granger causality tests of the five regions, we
found that in Egyptian, South Asia, Central PMN, Polity upsweep/upswing Granger
cause City upsweep/upswing. In East
Asian PMN, City upsweep/upswing Granger cause Polity upsweep/upswing. Further, we found that in Mesopotamian and East Asian PMN, city
upsweep/upswing Granger cause polarity, but in Egyptian, Central PMN polarity Granger cause city
upsweep/upswing. In South Asian PMN,
polarity Granger cause polity upsweep/upswing. (check)
To do: look at graphs for leads
and lags and comment upon these. Figure
out why the subperiods for the East Asian and Central PMNs are different.
·
Count the
swings and sweeps. Compare these with counts and tables in earlier studies. Compare the figs. How often is the largest
city in the largest polity? Identify the
sweeps in the graphs.
·
Do time
series test of antecedence (Granger causality). Pick a sample of swings and
figure out what caused them by reading the histories.
·
study the
city size distribution by adding the 2nd largest city in each system
at each time point.
Bibliography
6000 Years of Urban Growth http://www.citylab.com/housing/2016/06/watch-6000-years-of-urbanization-in-3-minutes-max-galka-metrocosm/487142/
Abu-Lughod, Janet Lippman 1989. Before
European Hegemony The World System A.D. 1250-1350 New York: Oxford
University Press.
Adams, Robert McCormick 1981 The Heartland
of Cities: Surveys of Ancient Settlement and Land Use on the Central
Floodplain of the Euphrates. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Algaze, Guillermo 1993. The Uruk World System: The Dynamics
of Expansion of Early Mesopotamian Civilization Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
. 2000. “The prehistory of imperialism: the case of Uruk period
Mesopotamia” in M. Rothman (ed.) Uruk
Mesopotamia and its Neighbors: Cross-cultural Interactions and their
Consequences in the Era of State Formation. Santa Fe: School of the
Americas
Anderson, E. N. and Christopher Chase-Dunn 2005. “The Rise
and Fall of Great Powers” in Christopher Chase-Dunn and E.N. Anderson
(eds.) The Historical Evolution
of World-Systems. London: Palgrave.
Álvarez, Alexis. E.N.
Anderson, Elisse Basmajian, Hiroko Inoue, Christian Jaworski,
Alina Khan, Kirk Lawrence, Andrew Owen, Anthony
Roberts, Panu Suppatkul and Christopher Chase-Dunn 2013
Comparing World-Systems: Empire Upsweeps and Non-core marcher states Since the
Bronze Age” Presented at the annual meeting of the American Sociological
Association, New York, August
https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows56/irows56.htm
Amin, Samir 1980. Class and Nation,
Historically and in the Current Crisis. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Anderson, E. N. and Christopher Chase-Dunn “The
Rise and Fall of Great Powers” in Christopher Chase- Dunn and E.N. Anderson
(eds.) 2005. The Historical Evolution of World-Systems. London: Palgrave.
Arrighi, Giovanni 1994. The Long
Twentieth Century. London: Verso.
______ . 2008 Adam Smith
in Beijing. London: Verso.
Arrighi, Giovanni, Takeshi Hamashita, and Mark
Selden 2003 The Resurgence of East Asia: 500, 150 and 50 Year
Perspectives. London: Routledge
ARVE
Population World Atlas http://arve.unil.ch/popmap
Bairoch,
Paul 1988 Cities and economic development:
from the dawn of history to the present Chicago:
University of Chicago Press
Bairoch, Paul, Jean Batou and
Pierre Chevre 1988 The Population of
European Cities, 800 to 1850: Data Bank and Short Summary of Results.
Geneva: Librairie Droz, 11 rue Massot.
.
1988 The population of European cities. Data bank and short summary of results:
800-1850, La population des villes europeennes. Banque de donnees et analyse
sommaire des resultats: 800-1850. Geneva, Switzerland, Librairie Droz. http://www.popline.org/node/366534
Barfield, Thomas J. 1989 The Perilous
Frontier: Nomadic Empires and China. Cambridge, MA.: Blackwell
Beaujard, Philippe. 2005 “The Indian Ocean in
Eurasian and African World-Systems Before the Sixteenth Century.” Journal of World History 16,4:411-465.
______ . 2012a Les mondes de l’océan Indien Tome
I: De la formation de l’État au premier système-monde
Afro-Eurasien (4e millénaire av. J.-C. – 6e
siècle apr. J.-C.). Paris: Armand Colin.
______ . 2010. “From Three possible Iron-Age
World-Systems to a Single Afro-Eurasian World-System.” Journal of World
History 21:1(March):1-43.
______ . 2112b Les mondes de l’océan Indien Tome
II: L’océan Indien,
au coeur des globalisations de l’ancien Monde du
7e au 15e siècle. Paris: Armand Colin Beckwith, I. Christopher. 1991. "The
Impact of the Horse and Silk Trade on the Economies of T'ang China
and the Uighur Empire." Journal of the Economic and Social History
of the Orient 34:2:183-198.
Bentley, Jerry H. 1993. Old
World Encounters: Cross-Cultural Contacts and Exchanges in Pre-Modern Times.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Blanton, Richard E., Stephen A. Kowalewski,
and Gary Feinman. 1992. "The Mesoamerican World-System."
Review 15:3(Summer):418-426.
Bosworth, Andrew 1995 "World cities and world
economic cycles" Pp. 206-228 in Stephen Sanderson (ed.) Civilizations
and World Systems. Walnut Creek,CA.: Altamira.
Braudel, Fernand 1972 The Mediterranean and
the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip II. New York: Harper and
Row, 2 vol.
______ . 1984. The
Perspective of the World, Volume 3 of Civilization and Capitalism.
Berkeley: University of California Press.
Brecke, Peter 2001 “The Long-Term Patterns of Violent Conflict in
Different Regions of the World” http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.15.9141&rep=rep1&type=pdf
__________ nd Conflict Catalogue http://www.cgeh.nl/data#conflict
Brown, Barton M. 1987 “Population estimation from floor area,” Behavior Science Research 21:1-49.
Chandler, Tertius and
Gerald Fox 1974 Three Thousand Years of
Urban Growth. New York: Academic Press
Chandler, Tertius 1987 Four
Thousand Years of Urban Growth: An Historical Census. Lewiston, N.Y.: Edwin
Mellon Press
Chase-Dunn, Christopher 1985 "The system of
world cities: A.D. 800-1975." Pp. 269-292 in Michael Timberlake (ed.) Urbanization
in the World-Economy, New York: Academic Press.
Chase-Dunn, C. 1988. "Comparing
world-systems: Toward a theory of semiperipheral development," Comparative
Civilizations Review, 19:29-66, Fall.
Chase-Dunn, C and Thomas D. Hall
1993"Comparing World-Systems: Concepts and Working
Hypotheses" Social Forces 71:4(June):851-886.
______ . 1997 Rise and Demise:
Comparing World-Systems Boulder, CO.: Westview Press.
Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Thomas D. Hall, & Peter Turchin. 2007
“World-Systems in the Biogeosphere: Urbanization, State Formation, and Climate
Change Since the Iron Age.” Pp.132-148 in The World System and the Earth
System: Global Socioenvironmental Change and Sustainability Since the Neolithic,
edited by Alf Hornborg and Carole L. Crumley. Walnut Creek, CA: Left Coast
Books.
Chase-Dunn, C. and Susan Manning, 2002 "City systems and world-systems: four millennia of
city growth and decline," Cross-Cultural
Research 36, 4: 379-398 (November
Chase-Dunn, C. , Susan Manning and Thomas D. Hall
2000 “Rise and fall: East-West synchronicity and South Asia exceptionalism
reexamined,” Social Science History. 24,4:727-754.
Chase-Dunn C. and Alice Willard 1994 "Cities
in the Central Political-Military Network since CE 1200" Comparative
Civilizations Review, 30:104-32 (Spring).
Chase-Dunn,C.
Alexis Alvarez, and Daniel Pasciuti 2005 "Power and Size; urbanization and empire
formation in world-systems" Pp.
92-112 in C. Chase-Dunn and E.N. Anderson (eds.) The Historical
Evolution
of
World-Systems. New York: Palgrave.
Chase-Dunn, C. Daniel Pasciuti, Alexis
Alvarez and Thomas D. Hall. 2006 “Waves of Globalization and
Semiperipheral
Development in the Ancient Mesopotamian and Egyptian World-Systems” Pp.
114-138
in Barry Gills and William R. Thompson (eds.), Globalization and Global
History London: Routledge.
Chase-Dunn, C. and Andrew K. Jorgenson 2003
“Regions and Interaction Networks: an institutional materialist
perspective,” International Journal of Comparative Sociology44,1:433-450.
Chase-Dunn, C. Eugene N.
Anderson, Hiroko Inoue, Alexis Álvarez, Lulin Bao, Rebecca Álvarez,
Alina Khan and Christian Jaworski 2013 “Semiperipheral Capitalist
City-States and the Commodification of Wealth, Land, and
Labor Since the Bronze Age” IROWS Working Paper #79 available at https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows79/irows79.htm
Chase-Dunn,
C and Bruce Lerro 2014 Social
Change: Globalization from the Stone Age to the Present. Boulder, CO:
Paradigm.
Chase-Dunn,
Christopher and Daniel Pasciuti 2004. “Review of George Modelski’s (2003) World Cities, -3000 to 2000,”
Washington, DC: FAROS 2000. http://www.irows.ucr.edu/cd/reviews/modrev.htm
Chase-Dunn,C. David Wilkinson, E.N. Anderson, Hiroko Inoue and
Robert Denemark Time Mapping Globalization since the Bronze Age IROWS Working Paper # 100.
Chase-Dunn, C. Hiroko Inoue, Teresa Neal, and
Evan Heimlich “The
Development of World-Systems”
Sociology
of Development 1,1: xx-xx,
Chase-Dunn,
C. and Marilyn Grell-Brisk 2016 “Uneven and Combined Development in the Sociocultural
Evolution of World-Systems” Pp. 205-218 in Alexander Anievas and Kamran Matin (eds.) Historical
Sociology and World History: Uneven and Combined
Development over the Longue Durée New York: Rowman
and Littlefield.
Chase-Dunn,
C and Hiroki Inoue 2017 “Spirals
of sociocultural evolution within polities and in interpolity
systems” To be presented at the
annual meeting of the International Studies Association, Baltimore,
MD,
February 22-25. 2017
Chase-Dunn, C., Hiroko Inoue and E.N. Anderson 2017 “The Growth of
Hangzhou and the Geopolitical
Context
in East Asia” IROWS Working Paper # 111. https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows111/irows111.htm
Chase-Dunn, C., Hiroko Inoue and Teresa
Neal. Forthcoming “High Bar Rules of Thumb for
Time-Mapping Systemic Human Interaction Networks. Pp. xxxx in C. Chase-Dunn and Hiroko
Inoue (eds.) Systemic
Boundaries: Time Mapping Globalization since
the BronzeAge Vienna: Springer-Verlag GmbH
Chase-Dunn, C.,
Hiroko Inoue, Eugene Anderson and David Wilkinson 2017 The SETPOL Framework:
Settlements and polities in
World-Systems” IROWS Working Paper #116 available at https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows116/irows116.htm
Chew, Sing C. 2001 World ecological degradation:
accumulation, urbanization, and deforestation, 3000 B.C.-A.D. Walnut
Creek, CA: Altamira Press
______ . 2007 The Recurring Dark Ages:
ecological stress, climate changes, and system transformation Walnut
Creek, CA: Altamira Press.
Cioffi-Revilla, Claudio 2001 “Origins of the
international system: Mesopotamian and West Asian Polities, 6000 BC to 1500 BC”
http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.189.2373&rep=rep1&type=pdf
Cioffi-Revilla,
Claudio and David Lai 1995 War and Politics in Ancient
China, 2700 to 722 B.C.:
Measurement and Comparative
Analysis, Journal of Conflict Resolution
39(3) 467–494.
__________________________________
2001 Chinese Warfare and Politics in the Ancient East Asian
International System, ca. 2700 B.C.
to 722 B.C., International Interactions
26(4) 2: 347–378.
____________________
and Todd Landman 1999 Evolution of Maya Polities in the Ancient
Mesoamerican System, International Studies Quarterly 43(4)
1999: 559–98.
Davis, Kingsley 1969. World Urbanization
1950-1970, Volume 1. Institute of International Studies, University of
California, Berkeley.
DeWinter, Walter 2016 “Globalization in Nubia during the Middle Kingdom
and the Second
Intermediate Period
(2000- 1500 B.C.) https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows99/irows99.htm
Economist.
2008. The
Economist Pocket World in Figures, 2008 Edition. London: Profile.
Ekholm, Kasja and Jonathan Friedman 1982
“’Capital’ imperialism and exploitation in the ancient world-systems” Review 6:1
(summer): 87-110.
Elvin, Mark. 1973. The Pattern of the
Chinese Past. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Fitzpatrick, John. 1992. "The Middle Kingdom,
the Middle Sea, and the Geographical Pivot of History." Review XV,
3 (Summer): 477-521.
De Vries, Jan 1984 European
Urbanization, 1500-1800 Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Fletcher, Roland 1995 The Limits of
Settlement Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
______ . n.d. City
and Polity Data Files, Personal communication
Flynn, Dennis O. 1996 World Silver and
Monetary History in the 16th and 17th Centuries.
Brookfield, VT: Variorum.
Frank, A. G., B.K. Gills, B. K. 1993 “The
Cumulation of Accumulation” Pp. 81-114 in A.G. Frank and B.K. Gills,
(eds.) The World System: Five Hundred Years or Five Thousand? London: Routledge.
Frank, Andre Gunder 1998 Reorient:
Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley: University of California
Press.
______ . 2014 Reorienting the 19th Century:
Global Economy in the Continuing Asian Age. Boulder, CO: Paradigm
Publishers.
Frank, Andre Gunder and Barry Gills
1994 The World System: 500 or 5000 Years? London: Routledge.
Freeman,
John R. 1983. "Granger Causality and the Times Series Analysis of
Political Relationships" American Journal
of Political Science. 27(2): 327-358.
GeaCron World History Atlas
& Timelines since 3000 BC. Luis Músquiz http://geacron.com
Goldstein, Joshua. 1988. Long Cycles: Prosperity and
War in the Modern Age. New
Haven: Yale University Press.
Granger, C. W. J. 1969. “Investigating causal
relations by econometric models and cross-spectral methods.”
Econometrica. 37: 424-438.
_____________ 1988 “Some Recent
Development in a Concept of Causality.” Journal of Econometrics, 39,
1:
199-211.
______________ & Newbold, P.
1974 “Spurious Regressions in
Econometrics”. Journal of Econometrics, 2,
111–120.
Hall, Thomas D., Christopher Chase-Dunn and Richard Niemeyer. 2009 “The
Roles of Central Asian Middlemen and Marcher States in Afro-Eurasian
World-System Synchrony.” Pp. 69-82 in The Rise of Asia and the
Transformation of the World-System, Political Economy of the World-System
Annuals. Vol XXX, edited by Ganesh K. Trichur. Boulder, CO: Paradigm Press.
"History
of the World: Every Year" territorial
polities since 3150 BC with nice music
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=ymI5Uv5cGU4&feature=em-share_video_user
Honeychurch, William 2013 “The Nomad as State
Builder: Historical Theory and Material Evidence from Mongolia” Journal
of World Prehistory 26:283–321.
Hui, Victoria Tin-Bor 2005 War and state Formation in Ancient China
and Early Modern Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
______ . 2008
“How China was ruled” China Futures, Spring, 53-65
Innis, Harold 1972 [1950] Empire and Communications. Toronto:
University of Toronto Press.
Inoue, Hiroko 2014 “Settlement dynamics and empire
dynamics: a comparative and evolutionary world-systems perspective” Paper
presented at the annual meeting of the American Sociological Association, San
Francisco, August 17.
Inoue, Hiroko, Alexis Álvarez, Kirk
Lawrence, Anthony Roberts, Eugene N Anderson and Christopher Chase-Dunn 2012
“Polity scale shifts in world-systems since the Bronze Age: A comparative
inventory of upsweeps and collapses” International Journal of
Comparative Sociology http://cos.sagepub.com/content/53/3/210.full.pdf+html
Inoue, Hiroko, Alexis Álvarez, Eugene N. Anderson, Andrew Owen,
Rebecca Álvarez, Kirk Lawrence and Christopher Chase-Dunn. 2015 “Urban scale
shifts since the Bronze Age: upsweeps, collapses and semiperipheral
development” Social Science History. Volume 39 number 2, Summer https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows89/irows89.htm
____________
, Alexis Álvarez,
E.N. Anderson, Kirk Lawrence, Teresa Neal, Dmytro Khutkyy,
Sandor Nagy, Walter De Winter and
Christopher Chase-Dunn 2016 “Comparing
World-Systems: Empire Upsweeps and Non-core marcher states Since the Bronze
Age’ IROWS Working Paper #56
Inoue, Hiroko and C. Chase-Dunn 2017 Spirals of Sociocultural Evolution: Polities and Interpolity Systems”
To be r presented at
the annual meeting of the International Studies Association, San Francisco, April 4-7,
2018.
Kang,
David C. Meredith Shaw, and Ronan Tse-min Fu. 2016. "Measuring War in Early
Modern East Asia,
1368–1841: Introducing Chinese and
Korean Language Sources." Int Stud Q. 60 (4): 766-777.
Korotayev,
Andrey, Goldstone, Jack A., Zinkina, Julia, 2015. “Phases of global demographic
transition correlate with phases of the Great Divergence and Great Convergence'
Technological Forecasting & Social Change Retrieved March 20, 2015 from http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0040162515000244
Kowalewski, Stephen A. 1982 "The evolution of
primate regional systems" Comparative Urban Research 9,1:60-78.
Lattimore, Owen 1940 Inner Asian Frontiers
of China. New York: American Geographical Society.
Lassner, Jacob 1970 The Topography of Baghdad Detroit:
Wayne State University Press.
Lenski, Gerhard 2005 Ecological-Evolutionary
Theory. Boulder, CO: Paradigm Publishers
Lieberman, Victor. 2003. Strange
Parallels: Southeast Asia in Global Context, c. 800-1830. Vol.
1: Integration on the Mainland. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
______ . 2009. Strange
Parallels: Southeast Asia in Global Context, c. 800-1830. Vol
2: Mainland Mirrors: Europe, Japan, China, South Asia, and the
Islands. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Liu, Xinru and
Lynda Norene Shaffer. 2007. Connections across Eurasia:
Transportation, Communication, and Cultural Exchange on the Silk Roads. New
York: McGraw-Hill.
Mann, Michael. 1986. The Sources of
Social Power, Volume 1: A history of power from the beginning to
A.D. 1760. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
McNeill, W H. 1982. The Pursuit of Power:
Technology, Armed Force, and Society since A.D. 1000. Chicago, IL: The
University of Chicago Press.
McNeill, John R. and William H. McNeill 2003 The
Human Web. New York: Norton.
Modelski, George 2003 World
Cities: –3000 to 2000. Washington, DC: Faros 2000
______ . Tessaleno Devezas and
William R. Thompson (eds.) 2008 Globalization as Ev. olutionary
Process: Modeling Global Change. London: Routledge
Morris, Ian. 2010 Why the West Rules—For
Now. New York: Farrer, Straus and Giroux
______ . 2013 The Measure of
Civilization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. http://ianmorris.org/docs/social-development.pdf
______ . and
Walter Scheidel (eds.) The Dynamics of Ancient Empires: State
Power from Assyria to Byzantium. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Neal, Teresa 2013 “The Sasanian empire and
world-systems research” Working Paper, Department of History, University of
California-Irvine
Pasciuti, Daniel
2002” A measurement error model
for Estimating the Population Sizes of Preindustrial Cities”
Pasciuti, Daniel and Christopher Chase-Dunn 2002
“Estimating the Population Sizes of Cities” https://irows.ucr.edu/research/citemp/estcit/estcit.htm
Pomeranz, Kenneth 2000 The Great
Divergence: Europe, China and the Making of the Modern World Economy.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Reba, Meredith, Femke Reitsma and Karen C.Seto 2016
“Spatializing 6,000 years of global urbanization from 3700 BC to AD 2000” Scientific
Data 3 Macmillan Publishers Limited
http://dx.doi.org/10.1038/sdata.2016.34 http://www.nature.com/articles/sdata201634#supplementary-information http://www.nature.com/articles/sdata201634
Rozman, Gilbert
1973 Urban Networks in Ching China
and Tokogawa Japan. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Sanders, William T., Jeffrey R. Parsons, and Robert
S. Santley 1979 The Basin of Mexico: Ecological Processes in
the Evolution of a Civilization. New York: Academic Press,
Scheidel, Walter. 2009 “From the “great
convergence” to the “first great divergence”: Roman and Qin-Han state
formation” Pp. 11-23 in Walter Scheidel (ed.) Rome and China:
Comparative Perspectives on Ancient World Empires. New York: Oxford
University Press.
______ . and Sitta Von Reden (eds.) The
Ancient Economy. New York: Routledge.
SESHAT: The Global History Data Bank.
The Evolution Institute http://evolution-institute.org/seshat
SetPol Project. The Research Working
Group on Settlements and Polities, Institute for Research on World-Systems,
University of California-Riverside https://irows.ucr.edu/research/citemp/citemp.html
Sherratt, Andrew G. 1993a. "What
Would a Bronze-Age World System Look Like? Relations Between Temperate
Europe and the Mediterranean in Later Prehistory." Journal
of European Archaeology 1:2:1-57.
_____. 1993b. "Core,
Periphery and Margin: Perspectives on the Bronze
Age." Pp. 335-345 in Development and Decline in the
Mediterranean Bronze Age, edited by C. Mathers and
S. Stoddart. Sheffield: Sheffield Academic Press.
_____. 1993c. "Who are You Calling
Peripheral? Dependence and Independence in European
Prehistory." Pp. 245-255 in Trade and Exchange in
Prehistoric Europe, edited by C. Scarre and F.
Healy. Oxford: Oxbow (Prehistoric Society Monograph).
_____. 1993d. "The Growth of the
Mediterranean Economy in the Early First Millennium BC." World
Archaeology 24:3:361-78.
Schwartzberg, Joseph E. 1992 A
Historical Atlas of South Asia New York: Oxford University
Press. eMap: Atlas: Document: English : 2nd impression.
Chicago, Ill.: Digital South Asia Library, Center for Research Libraries http://dsal.uchicago.edu/reference/schwartzberg/
Taagepera, Rein 1978a "Size and duration of
empires: systematics of size" Social ScienceResearch 7:108-27.
______ . 1978b "Size and duration of
empires: growth-decline curves, 3000 to 600 B.C." Social Science
Research, 7 :180-96.
______ . 1979 "Size and duration of
empires: growth-decline curves, 600 B.C. to 600 A.D." Social Science
History 3,3-4:115-38.
______ . 1997 “Expansion and contraction
patterns of large polities: context for Russia.” International Studies
Quarterly 41,3:475-504.
Smith, Michael E. 2016a "Why would a journal
called "Scientific Data" publish bad data? The Chandler/Modelski
city-size problem" http://publishingarchaeology.blogspot.jp/2016/06/why-would-journal-called-scientific.html
____________ 2016b “Bounding
Empires and Political/Military Networks with Archaeological Data”
Paper presented at the workshop on
Systemic Boundaries, March 4, 2016 University of California-
Riverside. http://wsarch.ucr.edu/archive/conferences/confname/papmike.pdf
Smith, Michael E. and Lisa Montiel
2001 “The Archaeological Study of Empires and Imperialism in
Prehispanic
Central Mexico” Journal of
Anthropological Archaeology 20: 245-284.
Taagepera, Rein. 1978a. "Size and Duration of
Empires: systematics of size." Social
Science Research 7:108-27. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/0049089X78900078
Taagepera, Rein. 1978b.
"Size and duration of empires: growth-decline curves, 3000 to 600 B.C." Social Science Research 7: 180-96.
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/0049089X78900108
Taagepera, Rein. 1979. "Size and duration of empires:
growth-decline curves, 600 B.C. to 600 A.D." Social Science History 3(3-4): 115-38. http://www.jstor.org/pss/1170959
Taagepera, Rein. 1997. “Expansion
and contraction patterns of large polities:
context for Russia.” International
Studies Quarterly 41(3): 475-504. http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/0020-8833.00053/abstract
Tainter, Joseph. 1988. The
Collapse of Complex Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Teggart, Frederick J. 1939 Rome and China:
A Study of Correlations in Historical Events Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Territory of polities since
3150 BCE https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=ymI5Uv5cGU4&feature=em-share_video_user
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Coercion,
Capital, and European States, AD 990-1990. Cambridge, MA: Basil
Blackwell.
Turchin,Peter 2011 . Strange Parallels:
Patterns in Eurasian Social Evolution . Journal of World Systems
Research 17(2):538-552.
Turchin, Peter, Jonathan M. Adams, and Thomas D. Hall
2006. “East-West Orientation of Historical Empires and Modern States.” Journal
of World-Systems Research. 12:2(December):218-229.
______ . and Sergey Gavrilets 2009
“The evolution of complex hierarchical societies”
Social
Evolution & History, Vol. 8 No. 2, September: 167–198.
______ . Thomas E.Currie, Edward A.L. Turner
and Sergey Gavrilets 2013 “War,
space, and the evolution of Old World complex societies” PNAS October vol.
110 no. 41: 16384–16389 Appendix: http://www.pnas.org/content/suppl/2013/09/20/1308825110.DCSupplemental/sapp.pdf
Turchin, Peter and Sergey Nefadov 2009 Secular
Cycles Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
United Nations
2011a Data on Cities and Urban Agglomerations http://esa.un.org/unpd/wup/CD-ROM/
United Nations 2011b World Urbanization Prospects: The 2011 Revision: Methodology http://esa.un.org/unpd/wup/pdf/WUP2011_Methodology.pdf
United Nations: Department of Economic and Social
Affairs, “Annual Population of Urban Agglomerations with 300,000 in habitants
or more” http://esa.un.org/unpd/wup/DataQuery/
Wallerstein, Immanuel 2011 [1974] The
Modern World-System, Volume 1. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Walters, Pamela Barnhouse 1985
"Systems of cities and urban primacy: problems of definition and
measurement." Pp.63-86 in Michael Timberlake (ed.) Urbanization in
the World-Economy, New York: Academic Press.
Wheatley,
Paul 1983 Nagara and Commandery: Origins
of the Southeast Asian Urban Traditions. Chicago: University of Chicago
Department of Geography. Research Paper #s 207-208.
White,
D. R., Natasa Kejzar and Laurent Tambayong 2006 “Oscillatory dynamics of
city-size distributions
in world historical systems”. Pp.
190-225 in G. Modelski, T. Devezas and W. Thompson, (eds.)
Globalization
as Evolutionary Process: Modeling, Simulating, and Forecasting Global Change..
London:
Routledge.
Wilkinson, David 1987 "Central
Civilization." Comparative Civilizations Review 17:31-59.
______ 1991 "Core, peripheries and
civilizations." Pp. 113-166 in Christopher Chase-Dunn and Thomas D. Hall
(eds.) Core/Periphery Relations in Precapitalist Worlds, Boulder,
CO.: Westview.
______ 1992a "Decline phases in
civilizations, regions and oikumenes." A paper presented at the annual
meetings of the International Studies Association, Atlanta, GA. April 1-4.
______ 1992b "Cities, civilizations
and oikumenes:I." Comparative Civilizations Review 27:51-87
(Fall).
______ 1993 “Cities, civilizations
and oikumenes:II” Comparative Civilizations Review 28:
41-72.
__________ 1994. "Hegemony and Social
Change." 38 Mershon International Studies Review, 374-376.
______ 1996 "Configurations
of the South Asia States System" 34
Comparative Civilizations Review,
Spring pp.
63-119.
______ 1999a “Power Polarity in
the Far Eastern World System, 1025 BC--AD 1850: Narrative and 25-
Year Interval Data.” Journal of World-Systems Research
5(3): 501-617.
_________ 1999b “Unipolarity without Hegemony." 1
International Studies Review no. 2 (Summer) 141-
172.
______ 2001 "Problems in Power Configuration Sequences: The
Southwest Asian Macrosystem to 1500 BC."
17 Comparative Civilization pp.
1-13.
______
2004a "Power Configuration Sequences
in the Northeast African World System to 1500 BC."
Comparative Civilizations Review (Spring), 82-104.
______
2004b “The Power
Configuration Sequence of the Central World System, 1500-700 BC” Journal
of World-Systems Research Vol. 10, 3. http://jwsr.pitt.edu/ojs/index.php/jwsr/article/view/279
______ . 2006 "Analysis of Power-Structure Fluctuations in the 'Longue Durée of
the South Asian World
System." 1 Structure
and Dynamics: eJournal of Anthropological and Related
Sciences No. 2 (2006),
Article 2. (With Sergei V. Tsirel.) http://repositories.cdlib.org/imbs/socdyn/sdeas/vol1/iss2/art2
______ 2008
"Hêgemonía: Classical and Modern Hegemony." 14 Journal of World
Systems Research no.
3, 119-141.
______ 2017 “When states-systems unite: Spatio-temporal boundary and transition issues in the
unification
of the Central, Far Eastern and South Asia states-systems” Pp. xxxx in C. Chase-Dunn
and Hiroko Inoue (eds.) Systemic Boundaries: Time
Mapping Globalization since the BronzeAge Vienna: Springer-Verlag GmbH
Wilkinson’s Maps: https://irows.ucr.edu/research/citemp/asa01/wilkinson.htm
Wilkinson, Toby C., Susan Sherratt and
John Bennet 2011 Interweaving Worlds: Systemic Interactions in Eurasia,
7th to 1st Millennia BC. Oxford: Oxbow
Books.
Wohlforth, William C., Richard Little, Stuart J.
Kaufman, David Kang, Charles A Jones, Victoria
Tin-Bor Hui, Arther Eckstein, Daniel Deudney and
William L Brenner 2007 “Testing balance of power theory in world history” European
Journal of International Relations 13,2: 155-185.
Wolf, Eric 1997 Europe and the
People Without History, Berkeley: University of California Press.
Wong, R. Bin 1997 China Transformed: Historical
Change and the Limits of European Experience. Ithaca: Cornell University
Press.
Yoffee, Norman
2006. Myths of the Archaic State: Evolution of the Earliest Cities,
States, and Civilizations. New York: Cambridge University Press.
____________ 2015 The Cambridge
World History, Volume 3 Early Cities in Comparative Perspective, 4000 BCE- 12
CE. Cambridge; Cambridge University Press
http://metrocosm.com/history-of-cities/
[1] A downsweep is a low point (trough) that is at least 1/3 lower than the average of the three previous troughs.
[2] World-systems are defined as being
composed of those human settlements and polities within a region that are
importantly interacting with one another (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997; Chase-Dunn
and Lerro 2014). When communication and transportation technologies were less
developed world-systems were small.
[3] Scientific studies of patterned social change do not need to
make any assumptions about progress (or regress). Sociocultural evolution
involves long-term changes in the degree of complexity and hierarchy displayed
by human polities and networks of interacting polities. Whether or not this is
seen as progress is a normative judgement that is up to the observer.
[4] Settlement is a general term that
includes camps, hamlets, villages, towns, cities and the great megacity urban
regions that compose the contemporary global urban system.
[5] This article reports results from a
research project on the growth of settlements and polities in regional
world-systems since the Stone Age. The
project is the Settlements and Polities
(SetPol) Research Working Group at the Institute for Research on
World-Systems at the University of California-Riverside. The project uses both
quantitative estimates of the population sizes of the largest settlements in
world regions as well as estimates of the territorial sizes of largest polities
to study the location and timing of changes in the scale of human institutions.
The project web site is at https://irows.ucr.edu/research/citemp/citemp.html. IROWS
collaborates with SESHAT: The Global History Data Bank and with the Big Data in
Human History initiative (https://github.com/IISH/human-history ).
[6] We use the term “polity” to generally
denote a spatially-bounded realm of sovereign authority such as a band, tribe,
chiefdom, state or empire (see also Cioffi-Revilla 2001: 4). Our study of polity size upsweeps is
presented in Inoue et al (2012).
[7] The normal cycle roughly approximates a
sine wave, although few cycles that involve the behavior of humans actually
display the perfect regularity of amplitude and period found in the pure sine
wave.
[8] This cutting point specifies what we mean by “significant” in a way that can be used to systematically compare widely different times and places.
[9] The idea of the Central
Political/Military Network (PMN) is derived from David Wilkinson’s (1987)
definition of “Central Civilization.” It spatially bounds systemic networks as
sets of allying and fighting polities.
The Central Political-Military Network is the interstate system that was
created when the Mesopotamian and Egyptian PMNs became directly connected with
one another in about 1500 BCE. The
Central PMN expanded in waves until it came to encompass the whole Earth in the
19th century CE. Because it
was an expanding system its spatial boundaries changed over time. We mainly follow Wilkinson’s decisions about
when and where the Central System expanded, and the temporal bounding of the
regions we are studying also follows Wilkinson’s dating of when these regions
became incorporated into the expanding Central PMN. The contemporary global PMN is the international
system of states. The merger of the
Mesopotamian and Egyptian interstate systems began as a result of Eighteenth
Dynasty Egypt’s invasions, conquests, and diplomatic relations with states of
the Southwest Asian (Mesopotamian) systems—first of all Mitanni, then the
Hittites, Babylon, and Assyria. The
signal event was Thutmosis I’s invasion of
Syria in about 1505 BCE. The fusion
of the systems began then but enlarged and intensified until 1350 BCE. Thutmosis III’s
many campaigns in Syria and the establishment of tributary relations, wars and
peace-making under Amenhotep II, as well as the peaceful relations and alliance
with Mitanni by Thutmosis IV, eventually led to
Egyptian hegemony under Amenhotep III (Wilkinson pers. comm. Friday, April 15, 2011). The final permanent linking of the
South Asian PMN with the Central PMN did not occur until the late 18th
and early 19th centuries CE when the British and the French
colonized parts of the South Asian subcontinent.. Before that there had been
several intermittent connections (Wilkinson 2017) that were not systemic or
only temporarily systemic with regard to geopolitical interactions. Wilkinson sees the final incursion as
beginning in the middle of the 18th century CE and becoming
engulfment in 1857-8 CE.
.
[10] Europe was never a whole interstate
system separate from the one in the Near East, though Wilkinson (1987)
specifies a short-lived separate Aegean state system in the early Iron Age
(1600 to 600 BCE). We wanted to use this Aegean PMN as one of our cases but we
do not have enough data points to do this.
[11] David Wilkinson (2018) has reconsidered
the extent to which earlier connections between the Indic and the Central
System constituted systemic political-military interaction. In earlier work he
contended that the engulfment of the Indic PMN occurred with the incursion of
Mahmud of Ghazni in the 11th century CE. Wilkinson now contends that
the permanent systemic connection occurred in the period from 1750 to 1858 ce.
We will use 1750 as the cutoff.
[12] In a later version of this research we will also use world regions as the unit of analysis (see Chase-Dunn et al 2017).
[13] Modelski’s city population size estimates
have been geocoded by Reba et al 2016..
[14] When we find discrepancies in the city
size compendia we read widely in order to produce better estimates (e.g.
Chase-Dunn, Inoue and Anderson (2017). Our template for a comprehensive city
size data compendium that will be contributed to SESHAT is at http://wsarch.ucr.edu/archive/data/setdataset.htm.
[15] The territorial sizes of polities are difficult to accurately estimate
from archaeological evidence alone.
Michael E. Smith (2016b) reviews the efforts that have been made to do
this (see also Smith and Montiel 2001).
It is usually not possible to obtain sufficient temporal resolution with
archaeological data for the kind of study we are doing here. Carbon14 dates
usually have a 200 year margin of error. When dendrochronology (tree ring)
dating is available, as for much of the American Southwest, yearly accuracy
makes the study of settlement sizes and polity sizes temporally feasible for a
study such as ours.
[16] The comparative world-systems perspective
developed by Chase-Dunn and Hall (1997) contends that semiperipheral capitalist
city-states (specialized trading states in semiperipheral locations in the
interstices between large tributary states and empires) were the main agents
that encouraged commercialization and the production of commodities in the
Bronze and Iron Ages.
[17] Claudio Cioffi-Revilla and David Lai have
also produced estimates of power configuration (polarity) for ancient China
from 2069 bce to 729 bce that correspond with the dates of the wars they have
coded. These estimates overlap with those of David Wilkinson for the period
from 1025 bce to 729 bce. Unfortunately the Cioffi and Wilkins polarity scales
are not directly comparable. To make them comparable we propose the following:
Wilkinson/Cioffi
Non-polarity
0 =0
Multipolarity
1 =10-11 and 12
Tripolarity
2=7-8 and 9
Bipolarity
3= 4-5 and 6
Unipolarity
4= 1
Hegemony
5= 2
Empire
6= 3
With
this conversion the Pearson’s r correlation coefficient between the Cioffi and
Wilkinson polarity scores in China from 1025 bce to 725 bce is .81.
[18] Wilkinson codes the Central, Mesopotamian and South Asia PMNs
every 10 years. The East Asian and Egyptian systems are coded every 25 years.
[19] In principle, we would like to estimate
changes in the level of interpolity conflict by including all the wars among
all the polities in each PMN. But some of the data sets include only wars among
the Great Powers (core powers). Brecke (2001:5) says "Assembly of the Conflict Catalog began in 1996 by
combining the conflicts from existing computerized war datasets such as
Correlates of War (Small and Singer, 1982), Militarized Interstate Disputes
(Jones, Bremer, and Singer, 1996), Great Power Wars (Levy, 1983) and
Major-Minor Power Wars (Midlarsky, 1988). From there I added additional
conflicts from Richardson (1960), Wright (1965), Sorokin (1937) Luard (1987),
and Holsti (1991).
[20] We revise the relative levels by century once we have better estimates
of war size (battle deaths, total fatalities) because the whole distribution
shifts because the total population goes up a lot, especially in the last 200
years. A small war in the 20th century is much bigger
than a big war in the 15th century so we increase the values of the 3
categories as we move forward in time. using the total human population
of the Earth as a guide in doing this.
[21] The estimates for the tables and figures are contained in https://irows.ucr.edu/cd/appendices/powsize/powsize.xlsx
The
Mesopotamia and Egypt results are using 100-year time intervals. The others are
using 50 year time intervals.
Level of statistical
significance: *=P = 0.05; **=P = 0.01; ***=P = 0.001; ****=P = 0.000. 2-tailed. The Pearson’s correlation
coefficient and significant tests require the assumption that the variables
are: (1) interval or ratio level (2) linearly relate, and (3) bivariate
normally distributed. For the variables
which do not meet the assumption of bivariate normal distribution, we used Spearman’s
rank correlation. The variables that used Pearson’s r are: Egypt year, Egypt
State, South Asia Year, South Asia City, East Asia Year, East Asia power,
Central PMN year (1500-700BCE), Central PMN city (1500-700BCE), Central PMN
state (1500-700BCE). The rest of the
variables used Spearman’s rank correlation.
[22] The
Mesopotamia and Egypt results are using 100-year time intervals. The others are
using 50 year time intervals.
[23] Our original version of this graph also
showed a peak city size in 1300 CE because we were using Modelski’s (2003: 63,
65) estimate that Hangzhou had a population of one million five hundred
thousand residents in that year. This caused us to scrutinize Modelski’s
apparent claim more closely. We found that the high estimate for 1300 was a
typographical error in Table 12 (Modelski 2003:63). On p. 65 he makes it clear
that the estimate of 1.5 million is for 1250, before the Mongol conquest of
Hangchou, not 1300. We decided to stick with Ian Morris’s estimate of 800,000
for 1300 CE. Our discussion of the difficulties of estimating the size of
Hangzhou and the role that East Asian geopolitics played in its growth during
the 13th century is at https://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows111/irows111.htm
[24] We do not include 1950 and 2000 CE in Figure 6 because the cities get so large that the scale
makes it impossible to see earlier variations.
[25] Level of statistical significance: *=P = 0.05; **=P = 0.01; ***=P =
0.001; ****=P = 0.000
[26] As
estimates of polity and settlement sizes for the Bronze and Early Iron Ages
improve we should be able to be more certain about what accounts for the lack
of positive cross-temporal correlations between city and state sizes in
Mesopotamia and Egypt – poor data or a truly different relationship during this
early time period.
[27] Granger
causality is based on linear regression modeling of stochastic processes
(Granger 1969). The Granger causality is
difficult to be applied to nonlinear data. This is the limitation of the
application of Granger causality since many historical dynamics are non-linear.
[28] The
assumptions of Granger Causality test are that: (1) the data are described as a linear model (?); (2) the data are
stationary. To examine stationarity of
the data, the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test was conducted. The test did not reject null-hypothesis that
the variables are not a unit root and stationary. A stationary
process is a stochastic process whose joint probability
distribution does not change
when shifted in time. Parameters such as the mean and the variance do not change over time.